Close on the heels of the Delhi High Court striking down
crucial "decisions" regarding service provision and interconnection taken
by the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India, the cabinet has decided to
institute via an ordinance a whole new regulatory framework. There are
three departures that are to be made in the new framework. First, a leaner
regulatory authority, which must be mandatorily consulted by the
government, is to be given well defined powers to investigate and make
recommendations with regard to a range of issues varying from conditions
and timing of entry and technology choice to service standards and
interconnectivity charges and tariffs. Second, these recommendations are
not to be mandatory on the government, which has the right to accept or
reject them. Finally, the TRAI has been stripped of its quasi-judicial
powers, but disputes relating to the policy or charges imposed must be
taken by service providers to a telecom dispute settlement and appellate
tribunal. Any appeal against the judgements made by the tribunal can only
be filed in the Supreme Court.
These revisions are expected to deal with the lack of clarity
with regard to the TRAI's powers, as well as the fallout of the High Court
judgement striking down the TRAI's controversial Calling Party Pays ruling
with regard to calls made from fixed to mobile phones. The High Court
reportedly held that: "TRAI cannot lay down the terms and conditions to
service providers on introduction of telecom service, installation of
equipment, technology and regulate in respect of the telecom industry." It
said that the regulator's powers in this regard were only "recommendatory"
and the Government was not bound to abide by the proposals.
Introducing greater clarity regarding the powers of different
institutions constituting the regulatory framework is, no doubt, a
positive step. Over the last three years, despite the existence of a TRAI
Act, which defines the role, powers, and jurisdiction of the regulatory
authority, the TRAI has repeatedly sought to extend its brief, putting it
on a collision course with the government. In this it has implicitly and
sometimes explicitly used three arguments. First, that by combining in
itself the roles of policy maker, licensor and operator, the Department of
Telecommunications has the ability to dilute or sabotage the government's
liberalisation drive, which threatens the monopoly profits that service
providers under its control have earned in the past. Second, that an
inappropriate licence fee structure that had emerged out of the process of
auctioning licences to the highest bidder, adopted before the creation of
the TRAI had resulted in inadequate entry by private operators, especially
in basic services. And third, that appropriate regulation requires the
TRAI to have a say in the determination of all aspects of telecom policy,
including licensing issues such as the introduction of new service
providers, compliance with licence conditions and revocation of a licence.
This implies that the jurisdiction of the authority covers not merely
service providers, including the service providing divisions of the DoT,
but also the DoT as a policy maker and licensor.
In addition, the TRAI has tended to behave as if its role in
this enlarged jurisdiction is not merely one of advisor but a decision
maker whose decisions are binding on both the government and the private
operators alike. This unilateral interpretation of the law, which the TRAI
went about implementing in practice, resulted in a most unsavoury
situation. First, it led up to a series of disputes between the DoT and
MTNL one the one hand and TRAI on the other, souring the relationship
between the two. Second, it encouraged private operators, who found
themselves unable to meet financial and other commitments made when
bidding for licences, to use the TRAI as the means to stall permissible
penal action against them. Influenced in part by its own conflict with DoT,
the TRAI has tended in these instances to rule in favour of private
operators, inviting the allegation of partisanship. In the event, the TRAI
found itself dragged to the courts which were called upon to interpret the
existing law defining the Authority's powers (See accompanying Box). The
court's decisions thus far have made it quite clear that the TRAI had
clearly gone beyond its brief, necessitating the current exercise to
restructure the regulatory framework.
But the new initiative does little to resolve the issues that
arose during the course of liberalisation and the TRAI's initial tenure,
relating to the likely consequences of the opening up of the telecom
sector (i) for the spread of the telcom network; (ii) social benefits of
competition; and (iii) the objectives and feasibility of regulation.
The Court as Arbiter
The decision of the government that the TRAI would not have
the power to adjudicate in disputes between the DoT as licensor and the
private operators as licencees merely incorporates into the legal
framework a judgment that had been arrived at by the courts in cases
which challenged the TRAI's tendency to unilaterally assume such powers.
Those cases were of two kinds. Those that challenged the TRAI's effort to
intervene in disputes between the DoT as licensor and private operators as
licencees, over issues regarding the implementation of the license
agreement. And those that challenged TRAI's claim that it had the right to
decide on the need and timing of entry of new operators.
The first of these became a problem when the TRAI decided to
hear a set of petitions filed by private operators in the paging and
cellular businesses against the effort of the DoT to encash bank
guarantees in lieu of unpaid licence fees and revoke licences in some
cases on account of non-payment of licence fees. Among the cases before
the TRAI were petitions filed by Netherlands India Communications Ltd,
Fascel Ltd, ICNET, Marcstat Communications, Koshika Telecom, Reliance
Telecom, Bharti Cellular and Modi Korea Telecom Ltd. The hearings in many
of these cases had to be stalled because the DoT filed appeals in the
Delhi High Court, saying that TRAI was not competent to hear disputes
between DoT (the licensor) and the licensees. It argued that under the
conditions of the licence, disputes were to be settled through arbitration
by an arbitrator appointed by the licensor. Following this appeal, the
Delhi High Court stayed further proceedings. TRAI on the other hand held
that DoT should not invoke the arbitration clause in the interests of
justice, since it was one of the affected parties.
The second controversy dragged to the courts was the decision
of TRAI to insist that it had the right to decide on the need for and
timing of entry by new operators into various telecom sectors. The
clinching case in this regard was the was the controversy over the
decision by Mahanagar Telephone Nigam Ltd. to launch cellular services
based on the CDMA technology.
On the basis of a petition filed by cellular operators with
the TRAI, the Authority issued an order in January 1998 directing MTNL to
desist from launching cellular services till it has decided on the matter.
Among the questions raised by the cellular operator's association was the
right of the government to provide a licence to a new service provider
without referring the matter to the TRAI. A month later the TRAI ruled
that MTNL's licence to enter the cellular mobile and paging services
business was invalid, since the Authority's recommendations were not
sought before the licence was amended in October 1997 to include the above
services. It held that the Government would have to mandatorily seek the
recommendations of the Authority on all matters pertaining to licensing
including those that involve introduction of a new service provider. The
TRAI simultaneously held that "the Internet policy, which was formulated
and announced by the Government without obtaining TRAI's recommendation...
cannot held to be valid." The order also held invalid the revocation of
licences of paging service operators, since no recommendations were sought
from TRAI.
The DoT, as expected went on appeal against the TRAI to the
High Court. In July 1998, Justice Usha Mehra ruled that the TRAI had no
jurisdiction over disputes between the licensor and licencees. In her
view, it could "safely be concluded that the authority (TRAI) fell in
error in concluding that the power of the Government to grant or amend the
licence is subject to the recommendation of TRAI or that these
recommendations are mandatory in nature." Having arrived at that judgement,
she went on to rule that she had "no hesitation to hold that the impugned
order (relating to MTNL) suffers from legal infirmities."
With the ruling that the grant or amendment of licence does
not fall within the jurisdiction of TRAI, all the cases in which private
operators had obtained a stay from the TRAI on imposition of penalties by
DoT for non-fulfillment of licence conditions proved infructuous.
The case against the TRAI expanding its powers into areas in
which it had no mandate was finally sealed with the most recent judgment
on the Calling Party Pays (CPP) regime notified by the TRAI. In its
notification of September 17, 1999, which instituted the CPP regime, the
TRAI "decreed" that incoming calls to a cellular subscriber would be free
(not subject to airtime charges). The cost of the call from a fixed to a
mobile phone, set at Rs. 3.60 a minute by TRAI, would be borne by the
latter, and the revenue derived from these calls were to be shared between
basic and cellular operators. The TRAI had said that cellular operators
would receive 80 paise per local call. The CPP regime was challenged by an
NGO, Telecom Watchdog, which argued that the new regime was unjustified
and placed an excessive burden on fixed phone users. Later the Department
of Telecommunication Services (DTS) and MTNL impleaded themselves in the
case. Both challenged the reasonableness of the revenue share fixed by
Trai and its rights to fix revenue shares.
In its recent ruling on the case, the division bench of the
Delhi High Court consisting of Chief Justice S N Variava and Justice S K
Mahajan not only struck down the CPP regime, but also the interconnection
regulation, issued by TRAI on May 28, 1999, which allowed the latter to
issue interconnection orders overriding licence agreements between the
government and private operators. The bench held that the TRAI had no
powers to fix revenue sharing terms between service providers. It
therefore asked the TRAI to work out a new regime in place of the CPP
regime earlier notified. With this case the legal position on the matter
of the jurisdiction and powers of the TRAI had been made amply clear,
precipitating an immediate announcement of a restructuring of the
regulatory framework by the government.
The Political
Economy of Regulation
The Telecom mess stems not merely from jurisdictional battles
and conflicting interests. It is primarily the result of the manner in
which, having decided to open up an area which lends itself to domination
by public monopolies, the government has, in practice, sought to muddle
through towards formulating what increasingly appears to be an elusive
policy framework.
The growth of the telecommunications services sector proceeds
through many phases, with significant implications for pricing strategies.
It starts with dominantly local traffic on fixed lines. Pure accounting
rationality would suggest that at this stage, the pricing of access should
cover average costs. As the network spreads, pricing strategies separate
the price of minimal access at a fixed rental and charge intensive users
separately for transmission and switching costs of actual use. Rentals are
kept low to attract low income consumers onto the network.
When the network develops further and the demand for long
distance traffic grows, the high usage value associated with such traffic
paves the way for subsiding local traffic with revenues on charges on long
distance traffic. The recruitment of new subscribers provides an
externality to those linked to the network, since the utility of the
network increases with size, accelerating expansion. It is after this
stage that any effort at reducing subsidies or cross-subsidisation is
warranted, with the focus not on increasing the cost of access, but of
reducing the cross subsidisation of local traffic by long distance
traffic. Meanwhile, new uses of the network result in diversification.
Available and increased bandwidth allows the network to carry non-voice
signals such as data, text and graphics. Here too it could be argued that
strict accounting principles should not be applied, so that users are not
discouraged from utilising devices and services (such as the Internet)
which have great potential.
This need to abjure an accountant's view of pricing thus stems
from a number of arguments. First, easy access to a telecommunications
network is normally considered to be a second-order "essential good" which
citizens are entitled to at a reasonable charge. Second, given the
externalities (or direct benefits to other economic activities) associated
with telecom access, the growth of the network is seen as yielding larger
benefits to the system than the immediate benefit derived from usage by an
individual consumer. Third, given the new uses generated by technological
progress which can have far-reaching economic effects and implications,
pricing should not be allowed to discourage diversification of uses of the
network.
These arguments in favour of a pricing strategy not based on
pure accounting rationality also make a case for leaving the
telecommunications sector to public utilities. Given characteristics such
as lumpy investment requirements and low profits at least at some
locations, it is to be expected that the service is unlikely to be
appropriately priced and satisfactorily provided by market channels. This
is likely to be particularly true in developing countries, where the
demand for such services is extremely uneven in spread.
If despite this case for provision through public utilities,
private entry is advocated on grounds of competition aimed at improving
service standards and on the basis of not-so-well-founded arguments that
available public capital needs to be supplemented with private capital to
efficiently meet the demand for telecom services, it becomes necessary to
attach conditions to licence provision and to cap prices charged through a
tariff-setting mechanism. A regulatory framework also becomes necessary
because private entry in most telecom services allows the private entrants
to earn rents on account of a number of reasons.
To start with, in areas like paging and cellular services,
entrants are limited by the need to allocate frequencies from a limited
frequency spectrum. This gives them an oligopolistic position which can
yield rents. Second, since provision of basic services requires provision
of the "right of way" to build the network crossing public property and
using public assets (like telephone poles, say), excessive entry can lead
to "congestion" with adverse social consequences. Here again those private
operators permitted to enter become eligible for rents. Third, even though
in liberalising mode, the government cannot allow unfettered entry into an
area which inevitably involves large sunk costs in infrastructure. In the
rush for occupying the market, the industry could get saddled with huge
excess capacities leading to waste. Thus, though private entry was to be
allowed, originally only two operators were to be permitted entry in each
circle. Finally, since the idea of opening up the sector is not just to
encourage the entry of private operators but also to expand the network,
private sector entrants would have to be allowed to interconnect with the
existing public utility network. Given the "externality" associated with a
telecom network, which makes the utility of a network a function of its
size, the private operator derives substantial "unpriced" benefits from
interconnectivity.
It is the existence of rents in all these forms that justifies
the levy of a licence fee on private entrants. The question remains,
however, as to how this levy should be computed. The problem is that all
the benefits derived by private operators are not from "goods" that have
markets. Hence the market itself cannot compute these gains on the basis
of prices it generates. It is essential that the government or any of its
regulatory arms should, on the basis of a detailed investigation,
normatively impute a cost to the benefits being handed over to private
operators. Rather than resort to such a procedure, and in keeping with its
belief in liberalisation and the benefits of the market mechanism, the
government decided to let private operators themselves 'price' these gains
by bidding for the licences on offer in the different telecom circles.
The result of that auctioning procedure is now history.
Private operators, driven by the liberalisation fever into speculation,
based on over-optimistic projections of market potential and counting on
unusually low costs of operation, made bids that were irrational both in
terms of the number of circles which were sought by individual operators
and the size of the bid in monetary terms. Once the bids were opened and
licences offered to the highest bidder, three consequences followed. Some
potential operators (like Himmachal Futuristic) withdrew their offers in
many of the less promising circles, delaying the process of identifying
the potential operators. Yet others bidders were soon convinced of their
folly by their inability to obtain support from financiers for their
proposals. And finally, of those who went ahead with their projects, quite
a few found themselves unable to meet the commitments they had made
themselves. Tables 1 and 2 provide the licence fee commitments made by
those operators who remained in the fray after the initial withdrawals and
Tables 3 and 4 provide the amounts which remained due as on
31 March 1999.
In such a situation, there are two approaches which can be
adopted. Within the logic of the liberalisation ethos, it could be argued
that the state should maintain its distance and make the investor pay the
price for foolhardiness. Bankruptcy and closure would follow. The bidding
process can operate again, and the new winners may be the same groups or
others who may buy up the infrastructure created by the original players.
The second approach would be one which recognises that the premise on
which much of liberalisation works - that markets are efficient - was and
is wrong. This would require a transition out of the current licence fee
regime to one which allows operators to remain viable. This was what the
government had decided to do, through a scheme involving a revenue sharing
agreement between DoT and the private operators, rather than a fixed
licence fee.
There were still two problems here, however. First, there was
no reason why those cellular operators whose irrational bidding generated
the mess, should be the natural beneficiaries of this transition.
Especially because their irrational bidding may have kept out of the
industry players who had greater capabilities in the telecom area and a
more sober assessment of market conditions. Second, writing off past dues
would amount to subsidising the speculative bidders rather than penalising
them.
Mr. Jagmohan, in his brief tenure as Communications Minister,
was clear on both these counts. He backed a scheme involving a one time
entry fee and a revenue sharing agreement, to implement which there would
be a new round of bidding in which existing operators could participate.
The idea was that, if the existing operator lost out in that bidding
process, he would be bought out by the winner at a price arrived at by an
independent valuer. But the transition to that scheme was to be
prospective. Meanwhile, companies had to pay up a minimum of 20 per cent
of their outstanding dues and securitise the remaining part. Some
operators agreed and obliged. Others like Koshika amd JT Mobile held out,
leading to a cancellation of their licences and a termination of the
connection to the DoT network. When the action was challenged in court,
the judges backed the Communications Minister.
Yet, when the government finally decided to make the
transition, it chose to sacrifice its Communications Minister, who was
moved out of his job, and let the operators get away without paying for
their folly. They were required to pay a sum equal to their dues on fees
on existing licences as on 31 July 1999 as an entry fee into the revenue
sharing regime. They were also expected to subsequently pay a revenue
share (tentatively fixed at 15 per cent) to the government. The actual
estimation of a reasonable licence fee was left to be computed by the TRAI
at a later date. This surrender to the private operators was the first
blow to the credibility of the government's regulatory framework.
But there was more to come. The next setback to the regulatory
framework was a result of the way the TRAI went about its task of fixing
tariffs. In its first consultation paper on Telecom Tariffs issued in
November 1997, the TRAI proposed that existing rentals on basic or fixed
line services should be increased by 63 to 140 per cent for different
categories of subscribers, the number of free call units allowed during a
bimonthly billing cycle should be reduced from 250 in rural areas and 150
in urban areas to 120 and that a uniform charge of Rs. 1,30 per extra call
should be insttuted in lieu of the existing sliding scale in which call
rates increase from Rs. 0.60 to Rs. 0.80, Rs. 1.00, Rs. 1.25 and Rs. 1.40
as the number of calls made increase. In addition, it proposed a reduction
in long distance call charges by upto 60 per cent.
It should be obvious that the intent of this exercise was
virtually to do away with two kinds of cross-subsidisation considered
acceptable in telecom pricing strategies: first, the subsidisation of
poorer, lower end users who are to be attracted into the network by lower
rentals and lower call charges for less-intensive use; and, second, cross-subsidisation
of local traffic with revenues from long distance traffic. While it is
true that as a network matures, an effort must be made to reduce the
extent of cross-subsidisation, it could not be claimed on the basis of
telephone and call densities that the network in
India had reached that
level of maturity. Nor was the extent of reduction of cross subsidisation
even in countries like France as much had been proposed by the TRAI.
It is not surprising, therefore, that the proposal which would
have adversely affected low-end users and benefited well-to-do business
subscribers was seen as a way of increasing the revenues of new private
basic services operators investing in local networks through an inequitous
rationalisation of the tariff structure. Despite calls for a moderation in
reduction of cross-subsidisation from Parliamentarians, the TRAI chose
early in 1999 to issue a note on the new tariffs and leaked to the press
the fact that it had issued such a notification. This again resulted in an
unnecessary brush with the Communications Minister and Parliament, which
was finally resolved with a structure which reduced cross-subsidisation to
a lesser degree but still provided some "relief" to new private operators
and high-end users.
The TRAI's actions cannot even be defended on the grounds that
its tariff setting principles are scientific. This comes through for
example from an anlysis of its tariff setting procedures for cellular
operators. The basic principle adopted by the TRAI is that rentals should
cover capital costs, while call charges should cover operating costs. Our
earlier discssion made clear that this does not tally with any economic
reasoning on how a utility like telecom access should be priced given its
characteristics
But what is even more disturbing is the fact that when
calculating costs, there was no effort to make a normative assessment of
what such costs should be. Consider the case of capital expenditures on
cellular lines to be recovered through the rental. Capital expenditures
consists of depreciation computed assuming a 10 year life span of
equipment and weighted average interest costs placed as high as 20 per
cent. Capital cost per subscriber is computed after taking utilisation of
equipment into account. To make the calculation the TRAI seems to have
unquestioningly relied on estimates provided to it by the cellular
operators themselves. The absurdity of this comes through when we look at
how estimates of capital expenditure per mobile line varied between
circles and metros and even across operators in metros (Table 5).
To deal with variations between metros and circles the TRAI
decided to base their recommendations on the metro calculations. But how
is the variation within metros to be dealt with ? The appropriate
procedure would have been to make a normative estimate of costs, which
would have brought the estimate closer to the lowest figure in the set,
since the nature of equipment used is more or less the same. The use of
mormative costing procedures is routine in the case of organisations like
the Bureau of Industrial Costs and Prices. Rather than opt for that
procedure, what the TRAI did was to ignore the abnoramally high maximal
value and then take the median value of the rest of the figures to arrive
at the capital cost with which rentals are to be computed when some
apropriate level of utilisation as been reached. This procedure is clearly
indefensible and would have inflated capital costs as well as the derived
rentals. It was on this basis that the TRAI came to the abnormally high
rental figure of Rs. 400 to Rs. 484 per month, as compared to the Rs. 156
which prevailed under the original tariff structure.
The above instance is just quoted as an example to illustrate
how there is nothing scientific about what the TRAI has done, making the
debate between it, the government and users a battle between those who
want "economic" costing and those who want subsidies, as it is often
presented to be. The problem with the regulation and tariff setting
framework which had the TRAI at the centre was that there was no internal
way to monitor the "monitor". This is what explains the repeated recourse
to the courts and the periodic clash between the TRAI on the one hand and
the executive, the Parliament and the consumer on the other.
The TRAI, of course, held that its procedures were correct and
that without hiking tariffs the process of introducing competition in the
telecom sector would be aborted. If that is accepted, then the message
which remains is that from the point of view of society and the individual
consumer the price of competition is too high and therefore liberalisation
is not warranted.
|