The
Indian rupee is on the rise. While its appreciation vis-à-vis
the dollar began in June 2002, when it had touched a low of more than
Rs. 49 to the dollar, it has been rising vis-à-vis the Euro as
well over the last four months. During these periods of ascent, it has
appreciated by close to 12 per cent vis-à-vis the dollar in 22
months and by a significant 9 per cent vis-à-vis the Euro in
a short period of 4 months. Not surprisingly, exporters have begun to
get restive; since a loss of 10 per cent in the rupee price of their
exports can shave off margins on past fixed-price dollar/euro contracts
and make it difficult to win new orders.
The rise of the rupee is partly attributable to the depreciation of
the other currencies, especially the dollar against those of its competitors.
That this was true for some time is reflected in the fact that while
the rupee was appreciating against the dollar for close to two years,
it was depreciating vis-à-vis the euro for much of this period.
This is, however, only small cause for comfort, since most export contracts
are denominated in dollar terms. Moreover, in recent months, as noted
above, the rupee has been appreciating against the euro as well.
Two factors have influenced this rise of the rupee vis-à-vis
various currencies. First, the excess supply of foreign currency, relative
to demand for current and capital account transactions from resident
individuals, agencies and institutions, other than the Reserve Bank
of India. Second, the willingness of the central bank to buy foreign
currencies to add to its reserves and, thereby, increase the demand
for these currencies in the market. The role of market demand and supply
in determining exchange rates and the consequent shift to market mediated
intervention by the central bank has been the natural outcome of the
adoption of a liberalised exchange rate system over the 1990s.
The pressure on the rupee leading to its appreciation, which is affecting
export competitiveness adversely, arises because India, which has recorded
a current account surplus since financial year 2001-02, has encouraged
and attracted large inflows on its capital account. India's current
account surplus, we must note, is not a reflection of its strong trade
performance. Rather, it is because, net inflows under what is called
the ''invisibles'' head of the current account of the balance of payments
has been more than adequate to finance a large and recently rising merchandise
trade deficit.
The principal sources of current account inflows have been buoyant remittance
flows and inflows under the ''software services'' head. That is, transfers
made by Indian workers abroad, either on short or long-term contracts,
have helped overcome the adverse balance of payments consequences of
India's lack of competitiveness reflected in a large trade deficit.
Inflows on account of software services rose from $5.75 billion in 2000-01
to $6.88 billion in 2001-02, $8.86 billion in 2002-03 and $9.09 billion
over the first nine months of 2003-04, while private transfers (mainly
remittances) touched $14.81 billion in 2002-03 and $14.49 billion during
April-December 2003, after having fallen from $12.8 billion to $12.13
billion between 2000-01 and 2001-02. In an intensification of this trend,
during the first nine months of the recently ended financial year 2003-04,
net inflows on account of invisibles stood at $18.22 billion, well above
the $15 billion deficit on the trade account.
Even while India's current account was relatively healthy on account
of the foreign exchange largesse of Indian workers abroad, the country's
liberalised capital markets have attracted large inflows of capital
amounting to a net sum of $10.57 billion in 2001-02, $12.11 billion
in 2002-03 and a massive $17.31 billion during the first nine months
of 2003-04. Expectations are that, because of the huge portfolio capital
inflows during the last three months of 2003-04 encouraged by the government's
privatisation drive, net capital account inflows during 2003-04 will
be in excess of $20 billion.
There are two issues that arise in this context. The first relates to
the nature of the capital inflows during these years. The second to
the implications of these inflows for the value of the rupee under India's
liberalised exchange rate management system. Three kinds of inflows
have dominated the capital account. An early and important source of
inflow during the years of financial liberalisation has been in the
form of NRI deposits in lucrative, repatriable foreign currency accounts.
On a net basis, such inflows accounted for $2.32 billion, $2.75 billion,
$2.98 billion and $3.5 billion respectively in 2000-01, 2000-02, 2002-03
and April-December 2003 respectively. They reflect the attempt by richer
non-residents to exploit arbitrage opportunities offered by the higher
(relative to international rates) interest rates on repatriable, non-resident,
foreign exchange accounts, to earn relatively easy surpluses.
A second important source of capital inflows has been portfolio capital
flows, reflecting investments by foreign bodies, especially foreign
institutional investors, in India's stock and debt markets, encouraged
more recently by the disinvestment of shares in profitable public sector
undertakings. On a net basis, such inflows had fallen from $2.59 billion
in 2000-01 to $1.95 billion in 2001-02 and just $944 million in 2002-03,
but rose sharply to $7.62 billion in the first nine months of 2003-04.
As compared with this, net foreign direct investment has been relatively
stable, at $3.27 billion in 2000-01, $4.74 billion in 2001-02, $3.61
billion in 2002-03 and $2.51 billion during April-December 2003.
The third important source of capital inflows was a financial liberalisation-induced
increase in the net liabilities of commercial banks (other than in the
form of NRI deposits), which rose from a negative $1.43 billion in 2000-01
to $2.63 billion in 2001-02, $5.15 billion in 2002-03 and $2.56 billion
during April-December 2003. This is possibly explained by the expansion
of the operations of international banks in the country.
In sum, capital inflows that create new capacities either in manufacturing
or in the infrastructural sectors have been limited. Much of the capital
inflow has consisted of financial investments that expect to earn higher
annual returns than available in international markets or obtain windfall
gains from the appreciation of the value of such investments, as has
recently been witnessed in India's stock markets.
Given the determination of the exchange rate of the rupee by supply
and demand conditions in the market, this large inflow of foreign capital
in the context of a current account surplus was bound to exert an upward
pressure on the rupee. When inflows contribute to an appreciation of
the rupee, foreign investors also gain from the larger pay off in foreign
currency that any given return in rupees involves. This tends to increase
the volume of inflows. The real losers are exporters, on the one hand,
who find that the foreign exchange prices of their products are rising,
eroding their competitiveness, and domestic producers, on the other,
who find that the prices of competing imports are falling or rising
less that their own costs of production.
However, this potential loss of competitiveness on account of surging
capital inflows was stalled for long by the intervention of the central
bank. By purchasing foreign currency from the domestic market and adding
it to its reserves, the Reserve Bank of India increased the demand for
foreign currency and dampened the rise of the rupee. The foreign exchange
assets of the central bank rose sharply, from $42.3 billion at the end
of March 2001 to 54.1 billion at the end of March 2002, $75.4 billion
at the end of March 2003 and $113 billion at the end of March 2004.
This implies that even after discounting for the increase in reserves
resulting from the appreciation of the dollar value of the RBI's Sterling,
Yen and Euro reserves, the foreign exchange assets of the central bank
were rising by around $980 million a month in 2001-02, $1.4 billion
a month in 2002-03 and $2.5 billion a month during 2003-04. Further,
because of inflows on account of the sale of equity in companies such
as ONGC and ICICI bank, foreign exchange assets rose to $116.1 billion
during the first nine days of 2004, or by a whopping $3.1 billion.
These magnitudes have two implications. First, they suggest that the
RBI has had to sustain a rapidly rising rate of acquisition of foreign
currency in order to dampen the rise of the rupee and preserve export
competitiveness. Second, that despite this sharp rise in the foreign
exchange assets of the central bank the task of managing the rupee's
exchange rate is proving increasingly difficult leading to a rise in
its value.
The task of managing the rupee is daunting because, when the central
bank increases its foreign currency assets to hold down the value of
the local currency, there would be a corresponding matching increase
in the liabilities of the central bank, amounting to the rupee resources
it releases within the domestic economy to acquire the foreign exchange
assets. If forced to continuously acquire such assets, the resulting
release of rupee resources would lead to a sharp increase in money supply,
undermining the monetary policy objectives of the central bank. Since
financial liberalisation implies abjuring direct measures of intervention
to curb credit and money supply increases, the central bank has sought
to neutralise the effects of reserve accumulation on its asset position,
by divesting itself of domestic securities through sale of government
securities it holds.
This process of ''sterilising'' the effects of foreign capital inflows
through sale of government securities has, however, proceeded too far.
The volume of rupee securities (including treasury bills) held by the
RBI has fallen from Rs. 150,000 crore at the end of March 2001 to Rs.140,000
crore at the end of March 2002 and Rs. 115,000 crore at the end of March
2003, before collapsing to less than Rs.30,000 crore by the end of March
2004. The possibility of using its stock of government securities to
sterilise the effects of capital flows on money supply has almost been
exhausted. Foreign investors have made a complete mockery of the much-trumpeted
''autonomy'' of the central bank won by curbing the government's borrowing
from the RBI.
In the current context, there are only two options available with the
government for preventing a capital flow-induced appreciation of the
rupee that could not just reduce India's exports but also deindustrialise
the economy and devastate agriculture by cheapening imports that are
now free. The first is to resort to measures that could reduce the volume
of inflows. A feeble effort in that direction has been the gradual reduction
in the differential between interest rates paid on non-resident foreign
exchange deposits and those prevailing in the international market,
as reflected by the LIBOR. The ceiling on interest on non-resident external
deposits had earlier been linked to the LIBOR and set at 0.25 per cent
above it. Now the ceiling has been set at the LIBOR itself.
But NRI inflows during April-December 2003-04 only accounted for around
a fifth of net capital inflows into the country, and that ratio is likely
to be much smaller in the subsequent months. Managing the rupee by controlling
capital inflows requires targeting portfolio flows. That is the signal
that the rising rupee sends out. Unwilling to heed that signal, the
government has decided to encourage outflows on the current and capital
account by removing the few import controls that remain, reducing duties,
easing access to foreign exchange for current account transactions like
travel, education and health and, most important, relaxing outflows
on the capital account by permitting firms and individuals to transfer
money abroad for investment purposes.
The dangers of blowing up in this manner the foreign exchange obtained
in the form of volatile capital flows should be obvious. What is more,
it is unclear whether this would resolve the problem. The process of
liberalisation may, in the short run, make India an even more favoured
destination for foreign investors. The rupee could appreciate further.
Exports could shrink. Further liberalisation aimed at increasing foreign
exchange outflows could damage the domestic production system. All of
which could finally encourage investors to walk out on India, in the
perennial search of markets that have not yet been destabilised. That
would deliver an economic scenario that no one would want to conjure
for this country.