While
economists of repute increasingly populate India's policy-making
establishment, holding regular or advisory positions, economic policy
itself seems ever more self-contradictory. Consider, for example,
the monetary and fiscal policy recommendations being made by this
establishment as reported by the media. There is a growing consensus
within it that the Reserve Bank of India should reduce overly high
interest rates to revive growth, even while maintaining a close
watch on inflation. In this view, inflation is a threat, but not
so much as to warrant stifling growth with high interest rates.
Responding to this pressure the RBI has in its recent annual policy
statement decided to go in for a significant half-a-percentage-point
reduction in the repo rate.
Meanwhile another argument is gaining ground that fiscal policy
should play a greater role in controlling inflation. The magic remedy
for inflation being recommended by adherents to this view is a reduction
in the fiscal deficit on the government's budget. Besides being
based on the belief that a reduced fiscal deficit would automatically
rein in inflation, this recommendation is noteworthy for the specific
way in which the reduction is sought to be ensured. The government
is being urged to reduce its expenditure to curtail the deficit
by raising administered prices and user charges and cutting budgetary
subsidies. More specifically, a case is being made out for raising
the prices of petroleum products so as to reduce subsidies or transfers
to the oil marketing companies. In recent times this establishment
demand has become an orchestrated campaign. The argument from sources
in the Finance Ministry and the Planning Commission seems to be
that if you raise a set of prices that would reduce the fiscal deficit,
the overall rate of price increase would be lower and not higher.
This push for raising administered prices to reduce the fiscal deficit
is supported by other similarly ''potent'' arguments. For example,
former IMF chief economist and advisor to the Prime Minister, Raghuram
Rajan, has at a function held to release the second edition of a
festschrift in honour of Manmohan Singh, reportedly called for a
complete freeing of diesel prices in order to rein in the fiscal
deficit and boost the confidence of foreign investors.
All this is confusing indeed. It is known that since petroleum products
are in the nature of universal intermediates, increases in their
prices inevitably have a cascading effect on costs and prices of
other commodities and result in an acceleration of inflation. And
since cost-push inflation is unlikely to be smothered by reduced
demand, it would be realised despite any reduction in the fiscal
deficit that may ensue. So, while the RBI is being advised to cautiously
stimulate demand and growth, while keeping a watch on inflation,
the Finance Ministry is being cajoled into stoking inflation by
hiking a range of prices.
This policy muddle is all the more disconcerting since it seems
to be accompanied by a misreading of the inflation scenario. The
case for reducing interest rates is backed by evidence that annual
inflation as measured by month-on-month Wholesale Price Index (WPI)
trends is much below its recent peak and still declining. However,
other evidence suggests that inflation in India still rules high.
According to the recently released Consumer Price Index (CPI) numbers
for March 2012, the annual month-on-month rate of inflation had
risen to 9.5 per cent from 8.8 per cent in February and 7.7 per
cent in January (see Chart). Since this new series of All India
Consumer Price Indices (with 2010 as base) are being released only
from January 2011, these are the only months for which inflation
figures can be calculated as of now.
Those figures point in two directions. First, that inflation at
the retail level is high and rising, especially because of inflation
in the prices of food articles such as milk and milk products, vegetables,
edible oils and eggs, meat and fish, besides fuels. Second, that
there is a growing divergence in inflation trends based on the WPI,
on the one hand, and the CPI, on the other, with inflation based
on the WPI ruling lower and falling from 7 per cent in February
to 6.9 per cent in March.
To recall, the official justification for the release of the new
CPI series was the argument that the WPI was not reflecting retail
price trends adequately and that inflation measurement based on
retail consumer prices was the international practice. The release
therefore marked the beginning of a transition in which the government
and central bank were to rely on this new index rather than the
WPI to compute the ''benchmark'' inflation rate in the economy.
Preponderant among the goods that enter the nation's consumption
basket and therefore the CPI would be food articles and fuels. The
supply of the former articles is more volatile (because of variable
monsoons, for example) as well as less responsive in the short run
to changes in demand. Their prices, therefore, tend to be more buoyant
than that of most other commodities. On the other hand, because
of political and economic developments in countries contributing
a major part of the world's energy supplies, the fuels component
of the consumption basket is also more ''inflation'' prone than
many other goods. In the event, there is a significant threat of
an acceleration of inflation as measured by the CPI.
Since according to that yardstick inflation is still with us and
would possibly climb, it could be argued that the RBI, which is
convinced that a hike in interest rates is the appropriate weapon
against inflation, was pushed into cutting interest rates at this
point. However, the muddle over policy seems to afflict the RBI
as well. In its recent assessment of Macroeconomic and Monetary
Developments over the last financial year, the central bank has
also come out in favour of increases in petroleum product prices
and other input prices to address the threat posed by ''suppressed
inflation''. That is, since the transmission of international prices
is inevitable, imported inflation can only be suppressed and not
avoided. And, if supressed, inflation is a threat. However, if that
be the case, since further inflation is almost a certainty, the
RBI by its own logic would be forced to reverse its interest rate
reduction decision. Why cut interest rates then?
Perhaps recognising this contradiction the RBI states: ''The upside
risks to inflation on the one hand and the depressed domestic growth
outlook on the other, warrant calibrated measures to maintain a
sustainable balance in a dynamic growth-inflation scenario.'' Presumably,
that is about as clear as one can get.
*
This article was originally published in The Hindu on 20th April
2012 and is available at
http://www.thehindu.com/opinion/columns/Chandrasekhar/article3336278.ece