It is almost like a slow motion replay of a
scene from one of those farcical black and white films starring Laurel and
Hardy, that some may remember from their childhood. The two men, in a
tunnel, observe the train, whistling and chugging as it comes at them from
the other side. They tug at each other's sleeves, gesticulate, accuse each
other of inaction, and generally do nothing useful, until the train
actually is upon them and splatters them both along the sides of the
tunnel.
Observing the
world's leaders and especially those governing the core
capitalist nations and the major multilateral economic institutions
confront the ever closer possibility of international economic
recession, provides a rather similar scenario. It is now clear beyond
dispute that the slowdown in world economic growth is not just likely
to be more prolonged than previously projected, but also wider, deeper
and with every chance of turning into recession.
Thus, forecasts
and projection of future growth have been revised downwards almost continuously
over the past two years, and the IMF's latest projection follow
a similar pattern. It is now predicting 3.2 per cent global growth in
this year, a full percentage point lower than earlier forecasts. The
United States economy, which was earlier expected to grow at more than
3 per cent over the calendar year, is now expected to increase by only
1.5 per cent or even less. Growth in the European Union is projected
by the IMF to be only 2.5 per cent in 2001, while the Japanese economy
is expected to expand marginally by 0.6 per cent.
The trouble is that even these projections appear to be optimistic in
relation to most recent trends, and may well be revised downwards even
further as the year progresses. Thus, the US economy grew at an annual
rate of only 0.7 per cent over the last quarter, and the Japanese economy
actually shrank by 0.8 per cent. Most recent figures from Germany suggest
that industrial output started falling in the last quarter, leaving the
level of industrial output only 1.1 per cent higher than it was a year
earlier. In Britain, manufacturing has slipped into recession by falling
for two consecutive quarters and total industrial production fell by 2.2
per cent over the year. Even France, which was performing better hitherto,
has shown a drop in retail sales over the past one year.
The proximate cause of all this is of course the continuing slowdown in
the only major economy which had served as an engine of growth in the
recent past – the United States. Over the 1990s, the US was the only major
economy that continued to expand at an impressive, even alarming rate. It
therefore provided a major market for exports from both other developed
and developing countries. The Latin American and East Asian developing
countries in particular have been heavily dependent upon exports to the US
in the recent past especially.
The UN's Project
Link, which involves economics researchers from over 60 countries, has
forecast global economic growth at 2.4 per cent this year, down from
4 per cent in 2000. It has blamed this deceleration on retrenchment
in major developed economies, noting that "the economy of the United
States has been at the heart of the current weakness in the global economy."
The recently released report of Project Link describes the spreading
downturn as "an intended one, at least in its early stage, engineered by
policy makers, in the first instance in the United States." The Federal
Reserve's aim last year was to "put on the brakes" on the rapidly growing
US economy in order to head off inflation. It is suggested that this went
on for too long and was too severe, creating a downturn that has now taken
on a life of its own. This is why it the downturn, which has lasted more
than desired, now appears to be relatively impervious to the series of
five interest rate cuts that the US Federal Reserve has already over this
year.
Obviously this US
downturn – which has not yet turned into recession but may still do
so – is bad news in a world economy in which the other major developed
countries are already shrinking or spluttering and where a whole range of
developing countries depend upon such growth because their own domestic
demand cannot sustain the required expansion. It can push other regions
into not just recession but full-blown economic crisis, of the kind that
is currently engulfing Argentina.
Given the severity
of the situation, what is really surprising is the absence of activity
among those who are supposedly in charge of maintaining a viable international
capitalism. A decade or two decades ago, such a context would have provoked
a flurry of meetings among the G-7, the major central bankers, and other centres of economic power. There would have been calls for concerted
action, for co-ordinated intervention by the governments of the core
capitalist countries, and there would have been much more decisive action
by the dominant player, the United States.
Instead, consider
what we have seen so far : only a series of interest rate cuts in the
United States followed by George Bush's tax cutting measure which
will provide, in the first instance, an estimated $300 more to be retained
by each taxpayer. These have so far not prevented the continuing slowdown,
and are not likely to do much more without other more substantial measures.
Now attention is focussed on the European Central Bank which is also
expected to announce an interest rate cut, as if that alone would be
able to pull major economies out of recession.
It is interesting to find
that Keynes's insights have been forgotten to such an extent that
policy makers still believe that measures such as these can suffice.
The possibility of a liquidity trap setting a floor for
real interest rates is real, especially in the face of depressed expectations
across the world, and this is amply shown by recent Japanese experience.
That experience should also make it clear that when people anticipate
bad times and more unemployment ahead, tax cuts can lead to more saving
rather than more consumption, and thereby contribute to a further weakening
of demand.
But the basic problem with
the world economy is not simply the bad macroeconomic judgement of those
at the helm. It is a deeper, more significant point. Charles Kindleberger
had pointed out many decades ago, in his analysis of the Great Depression,
that stable international capitalism requires a world leader, or at
the very least a multilateral institution capable of functioning as
such a leader.
Such a leader needs to
fill three important economic functions. First, discounting in crisis,
that is, serving as an emergency lender of last resort to economies
with international liquidity problems so as to avoid a more general
financial collapse. Second, providing countercyclical lending to economies
facing cyclical balance of payments difficulties, including especially
industrialising countries with more structural foreign exchange shortage.
Third, providing markets for the exports of other countries especially
in periods of economic downswing.
It is worth remembering
that both the historical golden ages of capitalism were
periods when one country fulfilled this role very clearly. During the
period of the Gold Standard, broadly between 1870 and 1910, Britain
functioned as such a leader, and through its capital flows enabled the
rapid industrialisation of countries such as the United States. During
the Bretton Woods regime of the 1950s and 1960s, such a role was played
by the United States, which had by then become the acknowledged world
leader.
In a sense, the International
Monetary Fund was set up to achieve at least two of these aims, although
its impact has been singularly limited in both. And over the 1980s and
1990s, the US economy did indeed serve as the engine of growth in terms
of providing a huge market for exports of other countries.
Increasingly, however,
it appears that the US is no longer willing to fill these functions,
and certainly the IMF is not able to do so, nor does it have either
the financial power or the breadth of vision required. In other words,
we now have a phase of international capitalism without a clear leader
(in the economic sense) which is able and willing to fulfil these
important functions. Phases such as these have historically been characterised
by great instability and quite frequently world recession as well.
So the current recessionary
phase can be seen as an outcome of policy sclerosis, but this in turn
reflects deeper changes in international political economy and power
structures. While this may well mean a more intensified recession at
the international level, this is not necessarily a bad thing for many
developing countries. Another thing that history tells us is that periods
of instability and confusion in the world economy are precisely those
periods which also allow for some autonomous industrialisation in what
has been called the Third World.
So, while world economic
recession is both likely and potentially painful, it may also represent
an opportunity for governments in developing countries to activate strategies
of autonomous industrialisation. The extent to which this occurs will
of course depend in turn on the various political economy forces which
determine policy in our own countries as well.
|