There
is a silent discussion on within India's economic policy establishment.
This relates to the way in which the combination of rising inflation
and slowing growth can be tackled. Till a few months back, when the
recovery from the 2008-09 downturn seemed strong, the focus of policy
was on curbing inflation. But now sustaining growth is also a concern.
The Reserve Bank of India has lowered its growth projection for fiscal
2012-13 to 6.5 per cent. Yet inflation is still high. Hence, as the
central bank puts it in its first quarter review of macroeconomic
and monetary developments during 2012-13: ''Persistence of inflation,
even as growth is slowing, has emerged as a major challenge for monetary
policy.''
Inflation is preventing the central bank from addressing the growth
slowdown by reducing interest rates. In the policy follow up to the
quarterly review, the RBI announced that it would as of now leave
key interest rates unchanged, and merely reduce marginally the share
of deposits that banks are statutorily required to invest in specified
government bonds. According to the governor of the central bank: ''The
primary focus of monetary policy remains inflation control in order
to secure a sustainable growth path over the medium-term,'' since
''lowering policy rates will only aggravate inflationary impulses
without necessarily stimulating growth.'' This declaration would disappoint
a private sector looking for some action to counter the slowing growth
rate.
The question is, can they turn elsewhere for support? Conventionally,
if the monetary policy lever cannot be used to combat a downturn in
growth, the burden falls on fiscal policy. But this too the RBI argues
is not all too feasible, because the so-called ''fiscal headroom''
required is not available. To simplify, the RBI along with much of
finance capital believes that the government is already over-borrowed
relative to GDP, and therefore needs to reduce its fiscal deficit.
Since an increase in aggregate expenditures, everything else remaining
constant, would increase the fiscal deficit, that is not the central
bank's desired option. More so because it believes that more spending
implies a larger fiscal deficit and a larger deficit would necessarily
aggravate inflation. The possibility that the government could mobilise
additional resources through taxation, and thereby expand expenditures
without increasing the fiscal deficit is clearly being ignored. So,
the fiscal policy option is being ruled out. The government concurs
in theory, though in practice it has let the deficit widen.
How then is growth to be revived? The consensus is that, rather than
spend itself, the government's role should be to incentivise private
investment, which would then drive growth. There seem to be two positions
here. The RBI feels that the government should spur growth by expanding
investment expenditure, since such expenditure would incentivise private
investment by generating demand and relaxing bottlenecks. To finance
such investments, it calls upon the government to reduce other expenditures
such as those on subsidies. The subsidies specifically to be targeted
are those on food and petroleum products, both of which would hurt
the poor. But this is a cost that must be paid, says the RBI, since
reducing such subsidies would keep the deficit under control while
getting growth going. Stated otherwise, while placing the burden of
fuelling growth on the well to do by imposing taxes that can finance
additional expenditures is not acceptable, reducing subsidies that
benefit the poor is eminently so. What is being discounted is the
possibility that increases in the administered prices of food (distributed
through the PDS) and petroleum products would both directly and through
their cost push effects contribute to inflation.
The second position on how private investors can be incentivised can
be traced to the government, especially the Prime Minister's office
and the Finance Ministry. It holds that ''big ticket reforms'', such
as allowing foreign direct investment in multi-brand retail or raising
the cap on foreign equity in insurance or privatising public banks,
are needed to unleash ''animal spirits'' and spur investment.
Even if not consciously, this argument advocates feeding the predatory
appetite for profit of big domestic and foreign private capital. If
profits can be inflated, capital would be willing to make investments,
it is being argued. This is in keeping with policy in the recent past.
Consider the period 2003-2008, when growth rose sharply, corporate
profits spiked, and corporate savings and investment boomed. The process
through which these occurred is revealing. To start with, since the
early 1990s, when liberalisation opened the doors to investment and
permitted much freer import of technology and equipment from abroad,
productivity in organised manufacturing has been almost continuously
rising. Net value added (or the excess of output values over input
costs and depreciation) per employed worker (measured in constant
2004-05 prices to adjust for inflation), rose from a little over Rs.
1 lakh to more than Rs. 5 lakh. That is, productivity as measured
by net product per worker adjusted for inflation registered a close
to five-fold increase over the 30-year period beginning 1981-82. And
more than three-fourths of that increase came after the early 1990s.
Unfortunately for labour, and fortunately for capital, the benefit
of that productivity increase did not accrue to workers. The average
real wage paid per worker employed in the organised sector, calculated
by adjusting for inflation as measured by the Consumer Price Index
for Industrial Workers, rose from Rs. 8467 a year in 1981-82 to Rs.
10777 in 1989-90 and then fluctuated around that level till 2009-10.
The net result of this stagnation in real wages after liberalisation
is that the share of the wage bill in net value added or net product,
which stood at more than 30 per cent through the 1980s, declined dramatically
and fell to 11.6 per cent or close to a third of its 1980s level by
2009-10.
A corollary of the decline in the share of wages in net value added
was of course a rise in the share of profits. The years after 2001-02
saw the ratio of profit to net value added soar, from just 24.2 per
cent to a peak of 61.8 per cent in 2007-08. The driver of this remarkable
boom in profits was a rise in the profit margin, or the ratio of profits
to the value of output. Increases in profit shares have clearly been
the result of the ability of capital to extract more profit from every
unit of output.
The question naturally arises as to the factors that explain the sudden
and sharp rise in profit margins and shares in the periods after 2002.
The answer is that in the name of economic reform, the government,
through tax concessions, transfers of various kinds and sale of land
and scarce assets to the private sector at extremely low prices, engineered
this profit inflation. But to realise those profits the private sector
needed a market to produce for. That market was delivered by a credit
financed boom in private investment and consumption, which rode on
the liquidity infused into the system by the foreign financial inflows
attracted by the concessions that the reform offered.
There is a major lesson emerging from this narrative. Neoliberalism
is an ambiguous and loosely defined term, even when restricted to
the economic sphere. However, an essential feature characterising
it is the use of the notion of a minimalist state to legitimise a
state-engineered shift in the distribution of income and wealth in
favour of the owners of capital and their direct or indirect functionaries
and conceal the conversion of segments of the state apparatus into
sites for accumulation. The limited evidence pertaining to the organised
industrial sector presented above suggests that it was the adoption
of such a strategy that allowed for a process of growth based on profit-inflation.
Sustaining such growth, therefore, requires sustaining a regime of
transfers to private capital. Under neoliberalism, growth is ensured
through a predatory regime of accumulation.
Those who advocate ''big ticket reforms'' are essentially arguing
that concessions or transfers to the private sector are required to
feed the predatory demands of capital to spur investment and growth.
The idea is to revive animal spirits with material incentives. Unfortunately,
experience shows that such growth while serving a small section of
private interests will leave much of the population marginalised and
possibly further impoverished. Moreover, the truth is that in the
current conjuncture this is unlikely to sustain even this kind of
growth. The real problem is slackening demand. Government spending
is being reined in. And the accumulated debt burden of households
and credit exposure of the financial system appears to be depressing
private demand. As a result the market that is needed to realise profits
is shrinking. More reform would not expand the market.
This seems to be generating a new policy consensus. One element of
that consensus involves spurring demand for the private sector by
diverting expenditure away from subsidies for the poor to finance
investment. That is the RBI's pitch. Simultaneously, a case is being
made for providing more concessions to cajole the private sector into
exploiting this opportunity. That is the government's take. This may
or may not help sustain growth. But it definitely would be damaging
in many ways for a majority of Indians. That would be the real fallout
of the obsession to keep growth going without resorting to taxation
or enlarging the government's budgetary deficit to finance that growth.
*
This article was originally published in Frontline, Vol. 29: No. 16
Aug 11 - 24, 2012.