There are other instances of a cavalier attitude when
dealing with evidence. Consider the following statement made in the
course of discussing misgivings that liberalization threatens a loss
of national sovereignty: "It is worth examining how China has succeeded
in achieving a high rate of growth and virtual abolition of poverty
on the basis of billions of dollars worth of exports of a wide variety
of goods." It definitely is worth examining why China's reforms
have delivered export success and India's have not. That the document
does not do. But it is also worth revealing that China's success
in eradicating poverty predates its reform effort and recent evidence
suggests that the loss of employment that has accompanied reform in
China threatens a return to poverty among some sections of the population.
Incorrect, or even dishonest, assertions of this kind
indicate that the intent of the document is not to prescribe the way
ahead to the Prime Minister of a country sitting on a consensus over
reform with little knowledge of what to do with that consensus. Rather
it is to pack a set of slogans into a pamphlet, which the authors presume
would be credible because of their own stature. Unfortunately, the validity
of that belief would not be judged by the market that the authors hold
so dear, since the document is available free of cost to those eager
to read it.
Even if there is some substance to the EAC's
belief in its own credibility, some far-reaching recommendations in
the report are bound to test it severely. For example, the document
recommends that the procurement policy should be drastically revised
and replaced with a support price policy that limits government purchases
to that required to prevent a sharp fall in prices. As a corollary it
suggests that the role of the FCI should be reduced to maintaining a
minimum targeted buffer stock of say 10 million tones and the PDS should
be supplied with grain obtained on the basis of tendering by private
traders. There is an obvious short-term problem with such a policy recommendation.
Since the government is currently burdened with stocks close to 40 million
tones, reducing stocks to the 10 million level would require offloading
huge volumes of the stock in the open market, which would result in
a collapse in prices. But the EAC could argue that this process could
be spread out over time, and that the 10 million tones target should
be seen as a medium term one. Even if that be so, the problem of price
stability would remain. It hardly bears stating that the monsoon-dependent
supply of foodgrains fluctuates much more than demand. So if the intention
at all times is to maintain a buffer stock of 10 million tines, in years
of good harvest open market prices would tend to fall sharply, and in
years of bad harvest they would tend to rise. A support price policy
of the kind being advocated can hardly ensure stability in food prices.
Another area in which the
EAC has been rather bold in its recommendations is the labour market.
Interestingly, while the report refers rather approvingly to the controversial
and non-comparable NSS 50th Round consumption expenditures
for 1999-2000, it does not mention the more acceptable employment estimates
that emerge from that round. They point to a very significant deceleration
in employment growth in both rural and urban areas, with the annual
rate of growth of rural employment falling to as low as 0.67 per cent
over the period 1993-94 to 1999-2000. This is less than one-third the
rate recorded during the period 1987-88 to 1993-94. In fact, it turns
out that this is the lowest rate of growth of rural employment in post-Independence
history. What is more, the employment elasticity of rural output growth
or the responsiveness of employment growth to output growth during 1993-94
to 1999-00 was also a third of that during 1987-88 to 1993-94. Clearly,
the period of liberalization has been characterized by a setback on
the employment front.
This however does not feature
as an issue in the EAC report. It is more concerned with increasing
the flexibility of labour markets confronting the organized sector.
In its view, the requirement that government permission should be obtained
for closure of units should be abolished or at the most restricted only
to units employing 1000 workers or more, as opposed to its applicability
to units employing 100 or more workers currently. This would supposedly
provide "employers with sufficient flexibility to reduce the volume
of employment or restructure producing units (or in extreme situations
even close them down) when changes in market conditions and technology
make it unavoidable." Given the trends in employment reported above,
none can take seriously the EAC's view that such flexibility would
generate new employment opportunities in the organized sector to an
extent required to balance for the obvious deterioration in employment
trends. The EAC is not just blinkered in its vision, it is clearly partisan.
What is of interest are the motives driving the EAC's
decision to issue a document of this kind at the present moment. The
intention could not have been a sudden desire to collate all reformist
policy propositions in one document to provide the Prime minister with
a reference book that aids quick recall. In any case, if it was, an
index at the back would have been of much help, as the quick-reference
manuals, produced for profit and sold to facilitate easy use of mass-market,
packaged software has taught all of us well. One possibility is that,
despite assertions to the contrary, it is the disturbing lack of consensus
about reform that seems to have driven the EAC to produce this report
and discuss, however inadequately, at least some of the misgivings about
reform. With the tenth anniversary of the reform in sight, discussion
about the gains from reform is bound to revive. That discussion can
prove embarrassing for a coalition whose political backing is to be
tested in the assembly elections that are imminent. The EAC report is
possibly an early salvo aimed at muting the damage that such a discussion
can have. Which is why it is surprising that some sensible people like
Dr. Bimal Jalan, whose organization is more circumspect in its analysis
of economic trends and cautious in advocating policies has signed this
report. At least he should have realized that a good start to the task
of downsizing government, which he advocates, would be a ban on the
production of such poorly reasoned and totally futile pamphlets with
funds drawn from an increasingly cash-starved exchequer.