Prof.
Jagdish Bhagwati, eminent economist and a strong advocate of free
trade, delivered a lecture on ''Debunking Populist Myths that Undermine
Prosperity – Lessons from and for Gujarat'' in the last week of December
2011 at Gandhinagar. The main message of the lecture was that Gujarat
economy is doing very well, not only in terms of economic growth
(with the highest rate of growth of per capita income during 2000-2010
among the states in India) but also in social sectors. He also gave
his certificate that Gujarat is on the right track and its economic
growth will (and has) automatically lead to social development.
He stated that Gujarat’s achievements in human development have
been better than many other states in the recent years: Gujarat
has experienced 57.5 percent increase in literacy between 1951-2011
– higher than what has been achieved by Maharashtra or Kerala; the
rate of decline in IMR between 1971-2009 was again better in Gujarat
than in these two states; and the increase in the life expectancy
at birth since 1970 also has been higher in Gujarat than in Kerala
or Maharashtra. Falling back on his favorite argument, he stated
that in the first phase of development it is important to raise
the rate of growth of SDP to generate revenues for promoting social
sector in the subsequent phase. Gujarat has generated revenues and
now it is promoting its social sectors.
One
major point we have with Prof. Bhagwati’s lecture is his use of
the data. Though Gujarat did experience a higher rate of growth
in literacy during 1951-2011 than Kerala (which started at a higher
level than Gujarat) and Maharashtra (marginally higher), 7 other
states have seen a much higher rate of growth in literacy during
this period. The decadal growth rates in literacy show that the
increase in literacy in Gujarat was of 18.02 percentage points during
1991-2011 (during the period of the new growth model), with the
state ranking 16th among the major 20 states in India in the rate
of growth. The state that ranked 4th in literacy in 1981, slipped
to 5th rank in 2001 and to 6th in 2011. Similarly, 7 other states
are ahead of Gujarat in the decline of IMR since 1970. When one
analyzes the periodical data of the SRS, one finds that the decline
in IMR in the state during 1991-2009 was 30 points with the state
ranking 10th among the major 20 states in India; and the rank of
the state in IMR slipped from 8 1n 1981 to 11 in 2001 and 2011.
Again, in the case of the life expectancy at birth also the rank
of the state slipped from 9th in 1992 to 10th in 2006, and with
the LEB of 65.2 years, the state ranked 10th among the major 20
states in India. In short, this fastest growing state has experienced
a deceleration in the rates of achievements as well as in its rank
among the major states in the fields of health and education. As
per the latest report of the Planning Commission, Government of
India, the state has slipped in its HDI rank from 4th in 1981 to
7th in 2001 to 8th in 2008, and the value of its HDI increased by
0.061 during 2000-2008, putting the state on the 18th rank in improvement
in the HDI. The recent reports of NFHS, Global Hunger (ICRISAT),
and other NSSO data also show miserable performance of the state
in human development sectors.
Under the present growth model (i.e. the neo-liberal policy framework),
growth is expected to trickle down to the lower levels firstly through
generation of large scale productive and remunerative employment
and secondly through redistribution of the increased revenues of
the government on social sectors for the masses and on infrastructure
development, particularly in lagging areas to enable them to grow.
In the first phase the focus is on raising the growth of SDP while
the second phase focuses on distribution of the increased government
revenue on social policies including cash transfers, poverty alleviation,
social protection etc, ultimately leading to poverty reduction and
human development.
Our recent study however shows that Gujarat’s performance has been
far from satisfactory in raising quantity and particularly quality
of employment in the recent decades. Gujarat has a high percentage
of informal workers (and casual workers) who receive repressed wages
(according to the latest NSSO data, Gujarat ranks 10th and 14th
in casual as well as in regular wage rates in rural and urban areas)
and poor social protection. Trickling down of benefits of growth
to the masses through productive employment has not happened in
the state.
The main burden of including the excluded therefore falls on redistribution
of the revenues earned through the high rate of growth. This has
again proven to be a difficult task, firstly because redistribution
does not change the basic process of growth that is responsible
for exclusion and marginalization, making redistribution efforts
increasingly weaker. Secondly, the strong vested interests that
developed during the first phase of growth are not likely to permit
the required level of redistribution in the second phase. The unholy
alliance between the capitalist class and the state has made the
state less pro-labour or even anti-labour. Thirdly, by gifting all
kinds of favours to the corporate sector to promote rapid growth,
the state seems to have promoted crony capitalism, under which the
corporate sector has flourished in the state. Instead of free market
forces, allocation of resources in the state is frequently influenced
by the distorted prices of factors of production. This has promoted
high capital intensity of growth with lower employment elasticity,
and high inequalities in incomes and assets. It has also left relatively
less funds for social sectors.
To sum up, the growth model in the state seems to have discouraged
inclusion of the excluded in the growth process as well as in the
redistribution process. Clearly, the model is not adequate to reach
development goals like full employment with decent work conditions,
rapid poverty reduction or rapid human development. It does not
seem to have the capacity or the vision for including the excluded.