That
the Enron-led Dabhol Power Project (DPP) was an enormous blunder is
now obvious to all. Not only has the Maharashtra State Electricity
Board (MSEB) been driven to near-bankruptcy, but a shadow hangs over
the completion of the $1.87 billion Phase II of the project. According
to reports, lenders meeting at New York may have threatened to stop
disbursement of $400 million in debt needed to complete the dominantly
credit-financed second phase. Their reticence stems from the crisis
facing the MSEB, leading to non-payment of dues totaling Rs. 262 crore
to the Dabhol Power Company (DPC).
MSEB's
inability to pay stems primarily from the fact that the revenue it
earns from sale of Enron power is far less than what it pays out to
DPC. According to one estimate, DPC accounts for just 6 per cent of
power sold by the MSEB, for which the latter pays as much as 33 per
cent of its revenues. According to the terms specified in the power
purchase agreement signed with Enron, the price the MSEB pays amounts
to the value of power that can be generated by DPC at 90 per cent
capacity utilization, with the price of each unit of such power being
computed on a cost-plus basis, where the plus is a predetermined rate
of return in dollar terms. The price (which includes a capacity charge
and a variable cost companent) equals at current costs Rs. 4.80 per
unit compared with the Rs.2.03 figure worked out in 1993, with 1995
as base year. This increase is partly due to the fact that the price
of naphtha, which is the fuel used by the project to generate electricity,
currently stands at around $300 a tonne as compared with the $180
price which prevailed at the time when the PPA was signed. Further,
the rupee has also depreciated during the interim from Rs. 32 to the
dollar to close to Rs.47 to the dollar. Since these cost increases
can, as per the PPA, be passed through to the price, the burden falls
completely on the MSEB.
But
that is not all. The MSEB has not been lifting the full complement
of power that can be generated by the DPC at 90 per cent capacity
utilization. That is because there are cheaper sources from which
it can acquire the power to service the demands placed on it currently.
In fact, the Maharashtra Electricity Regulatory Commission has issued
a directive requiring the MSEB to source power from the cheapest suppliers
first and then move on to others producers in order of cost. In the
event, estimates of the amount of power being lifted by the MSEB from
Dahbol vary between 35 and 60 per cent of the power generated by the
DPC. This has meant that the actual price payable per unit of power
sourced is much higher than the Rs. 4.80 mentioned above. For example,
the price per unit paid in October last year has been estimated at
Rs. 7.80. In that month, MSEB's dues to the DPC stood at Rs.
300 crore, while its revenues amounted to around Rs. 900 crore. In
December, the state's Electricty Minister informed the Legislative
Council that the MSEB had purchased power from the MSEB at Rs. 6.91
per unit between May 1999 and September 2000. Not surprisingly the
Board has found itself in a position where it is unable to meet its
financial commitment to DPC, precipitating a crisis situation.
The
Dabhol crisis, which makes the central government accountable for
MSEB's dues to DPC, has forced the government to reconsider its
plan to provide sovereign guarantees for three other power projects
the 3960 MW Reliance-SEAP promoted Hirma project, the 1800
MW LNG-fired Ennore project and the 2000 MW Pipavav project. But it
is not just the system of providing guarantees that has been challenged.
The encouragement given by the PPA system to the use of fuels other
than the much cheaper coal is also proving unsustainable. The National
Thermal Power Corporation (NTPC) has shelved its plan to set up a
2000 MW liquefied natural gas (LNG) power station in Mangalore, since
the tariff for power generated by the project is likely to be in excess
of Rs. 4 per unit, making it unaffordable, in the view of NTPC, for
the State-owned Karnataka Power Transmission Corporation Ltd. Interestingly,
Enron has argued that the cost of power supplied by it would fall
substantially in the wake of the switch over to LNG as fuel, when
a terminal for the purpose and a regassification plant are commissioned
at the end of 2002. In short, the government's policy of pushing
through a dominantly private-led expansion of power generation based
on fuels other than coal with the aid of a range of unprecedented
concessions to private operators has collapsed.
This
failure is however not just a reflection of an erroneous power policy,
but an indictment of economic reform itself. We must recall that the
terms on which the Enron-project was launched involved the provision
of a sovereign guarantee that protected the group of investors led
by Enron against three adverse consequences: first, the likelihood
that demand for power produced by it would fall short of levels warranted
by the size of the project; second, the likelihood that costs could
rise, as they have in the wake of recent increases in oil prices;
and third, the likelihood of a depreciation of the rupee against the
dollar.
Opposition
to the project stemmed from the sheer absurdity of this arrangement.
A sovereign guarantee of this kind, it was argued, went against the
very logic of private initiative, which presumes that private investors
would make their investments based on an assessment of likely returns
and the risks associated with realizing them. This would ensure that
investments are directed into activities, projects and technologies
where risk-adjusted returns appeared to be the maximum. They would
also ensure that the risks involved in choosing between alternative
scales, technologies and fuels would be taken into account when investment
decisions are made. Given that the Enron terms', which
foreclosed such influences on the investment decision, were being
given the okay by a Congress-government that had launched on a reform programme in which investment decisions were to be influenced not
by state support and subsidy but by market forces, the whole exercise
seemed to be suspect. Allegations that non-economic considerations
were entering into the making of the decision and that Enron was using
the opportunity to inflate capital costs and earn an even higher return
were other arguments advanced against the project.
Such
allegations were used by the BJP-Shiv Sena combine to oust the Congress
through an election fought, inter alia, on the promise that
the Enron deal would be scrapped. When voted to power, however, the
committee of experts' set up the BJP-Shiv Sena government,
and subsequently the government itself, not only ensured that the
project would go through, but added a second phase which would take
the size of the project from 740 MW to 2184 MW. The terms for purchase
of power from both phases of the project were worked out in advance.
It
is now clear that other considerations aside, the BJP's desire
to go along with Enron, despite its early opposition, was related
to its effort to present itself as reform-friendly. It was clear then
and has remained so since, that projects like Enron were a part of
the reform agenda, and would have been pushed even if non-economic
considerations did not play a role. This emerges from the arguments
advanced in favour of the project and the terms being offered to it
by different governments and by economists outside government supporting
the reform agenda. First, since a limit on capital expenditures by
the State in order to restrict the fiscal deficit was seen as imperative,
a much larger role for the private sector in financing investment
in the country was seen as inevitable. Second, it was argued, since
utilities like services were non-tradables, import was ruled out even
with liberalization, making investments within the country necessary
if growth was not to be stalled by infrastructural bottlenecks. Third,
it was presumed that the domestic private sector was not in a position
to mobilize on its own adequate sums of capital for infrastructural
investments, rendering foreign investments in these areas crucial.
The officially-sponsored India Infrastructure Report made a case for
attracting large sums of foreign investment into the area, and argued
that financial liberalization and financial incentives were crucial
to realize this goal.
Given
these presumptions, the profit-guarantee and terms being offered to
Enron were seen as a signal of India's commitment to making the
country an attractive and reliable host to foreign investment, and
opposition to the Enron project was even presented as anti-national
by some advocates of reform. These arguments were, of course, those
advanced publicly. But there was also a larger reform agenda hidden
behind the case being advanced in favour of the Enron project.
It
was widely accepted then and is accepted even now that much needs
to be done to improve the functioning of the State Electricity Boards.
Inadequate investments, poor maintenance and huge transmission losses
plague most SEBs. For the reformists, however, what was most galling
was the fact that for these and other reasons, such as the need to
price electricity keeping in mind other developmental and distributional
objectives, the SEBs were burdened with financial losses. Their prime
problem was to ensure that these losses were wiped out, independent
of the means by which that occurred. Combined with their obsession
with attracting foreign investment at any cost, this resulted in a
specific power reform programme. Privatisation, consequent to the
break-up of the electricity boards into generation, distribution and
transmission segments, as well as freedom to set prices were seen
as the essential ingredients of such a programme. An unstated presumption
was that if the SEBs were required to buy power from private providers
at economic' prices and bound by legal guarantees to meet
the financial commitments involved, they would be forced to raise
tariffs to cover costs'. Thus, projects commissioned on
terms like those offered to Enron were seen as a means of forcing
the state governments to dismember the SEBs and to change their pricing
practices in keeping with the reform agenda.
What
was missed in this perception was the fact that in a democratic polity,
policies to restructure the power sector can be pushed through only
if all stakeholders find them reasonable. In state after state, the
efforts to push through World Bank-inspired reforms in the power sector
have proved difficult if not impossible to implement. Agricultural
consumers are unwilling to accept higher charges when huge subsidies
and tax concessions are handed over to industry. Domestic consumers
see power as a facility that the state must provide at reasonable
prices to all. And many among the rich who believe even the present
rates are unreasonable find ingenious methods of bypassng the metering
system. This makes nonsense of the the effort to use private enterprise
in general and foreign investment in particular as the excuse to increase
tariffs to levels that could cover up the problems in the present
system.
Using
the Enron-type strategy in the name of reform only compounds the problem.
It is obvious to all that there are no markets working here nor is
their any reduction in the fiscal burden. Enron's profitability
is being protected by a government guarantee. And implementing that
guarantee for a high cost project like DPC is only increasing the
fiscal burden on the State.
The
Enron episode has in fact proved that the reform programme undertaken
on the grounds that subsidies need to be eliminated and the fiscal
burden on the government reduced is a complete farce. Vivek Monteiro,
the Secretary of the Maharashtra State Committee of the Centre of
Indian Trade Unions has been quick to point out that in the name of
eliminating subsidies the government has ended up providing a huge
subsidy to Enron. The PPA requires the government to find the resources
to pay DPC. Even assuming demand is equal to that supplied by DPC
at 90 per cent capacity utilization, and the price per unit is at
Rs.3.25 per unit, distribution and transmission losses would alone
take the price to Rs. 4.25 a unit. Taking account of the fact that
the average price recovered per unit sold by the MSEB works out to
only Rs. 2, the government has to provide the MSEB with and additional
Rs.2.25 per unit to meet its dues to the DPC. Since, just putting
in place a project commissioned on the Enron terms has proved inadequate
to either reduces distribution and transmission losses or raise the
tariff, the subsidy remains in place, though it accrues not to the
MSEB but to Enron whose profits are protected. In Monteiro's
view if Dabhol Phase II is commissioned the subsidy amount needed
to protect DPC's dollar profits would work out to more than the
total agricultural subsidy.
In
sum, an initiative that was launched as part of the ideology of reform
has ended by defeating the grounds on which the reform process is
commonly advocated. The question that remains is why the subsidy that
is finally being paid is being offered to Enron. It is known that
among the major creditors who have lent Enron huge sums on the strength
of the government's guarantee are a host of Indian banks and
financial institutions. If a similar credible guarantee had been provided
to an Indian firm, it could have accessed the same sources to earn
similar profits, which may not have been repatriated abroad in equal
measure. What benefit the policy has offered in terms of attracting
foreign investors who could deliver more than India corporates to
the country is by no means clear. And the fact that the policy has
only worsened the crisis in the power sector and elsewhere in the
economy has even begun to affect the credibility of the sovereign
guarantee that the government has offered. As noted earlier, creditors
have sat up and started questioning the feasibility of Phase II.
But the crisis cannot be
easily resolved. What is damaging is that the manipulative advocates
of reform have carried the process to an extent where redressing the
obvious blunder could prove costly. Under the prevailing terms and
conditions, if the government opts to pull back its commitment to
backing Dabhol Phase II and purchasing all the power it generates,
it would have to pay compensation to the tune of Rs. 35,000 crore.
Reforms are irreversible, even if disastrous, only because those who
devise them ensure that they can be reversed only at prohibitive costs.
If the ideal capitalism that the advocates of reform celebrate actually
ruled, all those who backed the project, including the "disinterested"
economists who defended it, would have been penalized. Unfortunately,
it does not.
|