Evidence that economic reform in
India has not managed to check or tame monopoly and promote competition
is growing. In some areas reform has fostered oligopolies. In others
it has served to consolidate the strength of existing oligopolies.
Combined with the fact that liberalization has taken the teeth out
of anti-trust institutions and policies, this has resulted in collusive
practices that have allowed these oligopolies to earn large rents
at the expense of consumers.
Consider for example the cellular
telephone sector. Hitherto it has been dominated by a few service
providers who won themselves licences by bidding to pay huge licence
fees, and subsequently reneged on their promise. Claiming that they
would have to shut shop if such fees were actually paid, and virtually
frightening the public and the government into believing that this
would ensure the mortality of an infant industry, they managed to
migrate to a license fee regime that reduced their burden substantially.
As has been argued by many, including some in government, this amounted
to condoning the error and providing concessions to providers who,
under false pretences, had in essence pre-empted entry by those who
had originally submitted lower and more rational bids.
Having won themselves an oligopolistic
position under false pretences, these operators, who combined under
the banner of the Cellular Operators Association of India (COAI),
have strenuously struggled to realize two objectives. They have sought
to pressurize the regulatory authority, the Telecom Regulatory Authority
of India (TRAI), to adopt a pricing principle and ceilings on tariffs
that permits the realization of oligopolistic rents, despite regulation.
And they have worked towards preempting competition from within and
outside the sector, sp that such rents are actually realized.
They were successful in the pursuit
of the first of these objectives because of the obvious bias of the
originally constituted board of the TRAI in favour of the private
operators that finally necessitated the reconstitution of the Board.
The pricing principle that was adopted provides for a rental that
goes to meet the capital cost of the provider and an airtime charge
that covers operating expenses. This ensured that there was little
risk left in the business. Other attempts to improve the profitability
of the business such as the demand for a Calling Party Pays (CPP)
regime, under which the caller meets the airtime charge for incoming
calls whether or not the caller was a subscriber to the cellular network,
were fortunately short down despite the then TRAIs sympathy
for the demand.
Given the rents implicit in the
ceiling tariffs specified, if the view, which dominates reform, that
the induction of private players into a business automatically induces
competition were indeed true, actual cellular tariffs would have been
driven well below the TRAI-specified levels. It did not because of
collusion between the operators that transformed an oligopoly into
a virtual monopoly.
What is shocking is the recent revelation
that the cellular operators had in fact even flouted the TRAI ceilings.
In a decision, which speaks for the credibility of the reconstituted
board of the TRAI, especially when compared with its predecessor,
the Authority has asked cellular operators to refund customers the
excess amounts they have charged subscribers since August 1999, when
the migration from the fixed licence fee regime to the revenue sharing
system tool place. In the wake of migration the rental and airtime
tariff ceilings worked out by the TRAI were Rs. 422 per month and
Rs. 4.65 per minute respectively. As opposed to this cellular operators
were charging Rs. 600 and Rs. 475 as rental for different time spans
during the August 1999 to January 2000 period and Rs. 6 and Rs. 4
per minute as airtime charges. According to one estimate, after taking
into account differences from the permitted maximum rate, subscribers
on the standard tariff package have to be refunded as much as 13 per
cent of the charges they have paid over the period August 1999 to
January 2001. Across the country, the collusive practices of the operators
have resulted in excess charges close to Rs. 400 crore.
Further, with the belated induction
of new competitors into the business, it is now clear that the monopolistic
position of the operators in different circles have helped them earn
large profits from subscribers, by keeping tariffs close to the maximum
permissible. This they ensured by preempting competition from outside
the cellular industry. Since its inception the COAI has lobbied against
the entry of new operators into the mobile telephony business, whether
as fully-mobile operators or operators with limited mobility. For
long, they managed, for example, to stall the entry of MTNL into the
mobile telephony business using GSM, CDMA or WLL technologies. It
has taken close to five years to break the stranglehold the COAI ensured
over the industry through these means. The moment MTNL won its case
to enter the GSM business in the Delhi metro circle with its Dolphin
service, cellular tariffs have collapsed by more than a third on average.
The willingness of Airtel and Essar to substantially cut tariffs to
partially match the much lower tariffs announced by MTNL indicates
that these providers had been earning huge margins relative to what
they would now earn in the new competitive environment. And with the
government having finally come around to the view that entry into
the telephony business must be freed substantially, it would be no
surprise if tariffs come down even further, revealing the extent to
which private operators (inducted into the telecommunications area
to reduce tariffs and improve customer service) have actually ended
up fleecing the consumer.
Advocates of reform would however
argue that, while some mistakes were made in the early stages of reform
in the telecommunications industry, the reconstitution of the TRAI
and recent revisions of policy would set things finally right. If
the TRAI plays the role of watchdog appropriately, it may. Otherwise
it would not, as experience elsewhere indicates. This is because competition
even if temporarily ensured, as it seems to have been in the telecom
sector, could soon lead to oligopolization. This is illustrated by
the experience of the cement industry, which has for some time now
been freed of restrictions on entry as well as controls on prices.
Liberalization did initially spur competition, which led to increased
capacity, an improved demand-supply balance and better prices for
the consumer. Cement production rose from 49 million tones in 1990-91
to 88 million tones in 1998-99, because of a wave of capacity creation
in the wake of liberalization. However, with public investment depressed
and growth in the construction business slowing, the industry came
to be characterized by excess capacities and depressed prices. To
help the industry the government stepped in with protection from international
competition with a basic customs duty of 38 per cent, a special additional
duty of 4 per cent, an anti-dumping duty of Rs.10 per tonne and a
countervailing duty of Rs. 350 per tonne.
Behind these protective barriers
the demand-constrained industry has been witnessing a substantial
change in structure. The industry has seen a process of growing consolidation
of capacity in a few hands as a result of a spate of mega-mergers
and acquisitions. Leading the movement has been international cement
major Lafarge of France that has acquired the cement businesses of
Raymond and Tata Steel and is reportedly gearing up for an acquisition
of Jayaprakash Cement. But there have been others in the game as well.
Gujarat Ambuja has bought out the Tata stake in ACC for Rs. 925 crore,
India Cements has acquired Raasi Cement and Italcementi has acquired
a 50 per cent stake in Zuari Cement. All this is occurring in an industry
where already capacity with the top six players accounts for more
than 60 per cent of total production, though there are 60 companies
and 120 plants in the industry.
Acquisitions such as these may be
dismissed as inevitable in a more market-driven environment. But what
is disturbing is that the process of consolidation has been accompanied
by growing evidence of monopolistic practices. The demand for cement
picked up in 1999-2000, as reflected in the 20 per cent increase in
output during the first eight months of that financial year. Using
the occasion, as well as the base for collusive practices that concentration
in capacity affords, producers have consciously jacked up cement prices.
Prices which were slack till about November last year, have been escalating
rapidly since, as leading producers repeatedly hiked prices supported
by measures aimed at reducing supply and creating an artificial shortage.
Thus in November, these producers had decided to shut down capacity
for 35 days more than the 25 during which capacity is normally shut
down for maintenance purposes. Restrictions on the distribution of
cement have also reportedly been adopted by what is quite clearly
an organized cartel. With the support of of such measures, prices
were hiked by 36 per cent in five successive revisions during the
last two months of 2000, taking the Mumbai price of cement from Rs.
140 a bag to Rs. 190 a bag. Other markets such as those in Andhra
Pradesh, Tamil Nadu and Kerala have witnessed similar increases.
The large increase in price over
a short period of time has met with an adverse response from the building
industry. The Builders Association of India has called for intervention
by the government in the form of import duty reductions and price
regulation and the Department of Company Affairs has reportedly instituted
an inquiry. The fact, however, remains that liberalization has done
away with many of the instruments that the government has at its command
to deal with cartels of the kind that have formed in the cement industry.
Reform not only engenders monopoly, it provides greater leeway to
oligopolistic firms to exercise their market power.
The difference between the situation
in the cellular and cement industry is worth noting. Though a new
industry, cellular operators have used the same strategy as the traditional
oligopolistic groups that flourished during the import substitution
years. Just as the traditional oligopolistic structure used the licensing
system as a means to prevent the entry of new players into their bases
of monopoly power, the cellular operators used the State including
the official regulatory authority to preempt entry and charge tariffs
that ensured high profits. The cement industry, on the other hand,
has seen the emergence of oligopoly as a natural result of unbridled
competition. And the withdrawal of the State in the wake of deregulation
has helped those oligopolies to protect and increase their profits.
The cement experience suggests that
even if recent policy decisions have helped reduce the strangehold
over the market of the early entrants into the cellular industry and
widen and intensify competition, this is no guarantee against subsequent
oligopolisation. What remains to be seen is whether the reconstituted
TRAI would be able to prevent those oligopolies, when they emerge,
from reaping unfair benefits from their market power. Even if that
happens, the lesson is clear. Markets freed by reform breed anti-competitive
practices. The State must come in to prevent them, as it must in the
case of cement.
|