In
moves that have surprised many, the UPA government has, in the midst
of a global financial crisis whose lessons are still being distilled,
decided to press ahead with liberalization of the insurance sector.
At the fag end of its term and in a truncated parliament session that
has other important business to deal with, the government appeared to
be in a desperate rush to table two bills to amend the laws applicable
to the insurance sector. The two bills—The Insurance Laws (Amendments)
Bill and the Life Insurance Corporation (Amendment) Bill—were introduced
in the Rajya Sabha and Lok Sabha respectively on December 22 without
adequate discussion in the midst of the din generated by the BJP’s demand
for the resignation of Minority Affairs Minister A R Antulay. Whether
consciously or not, the BJP has helped the government to keep alive
the issue of insurance privatization.
While it is unlikely that the government would be able to pass these
bills during its current term, it has by tabling them kept the process
of insurance sector liberalization and privatization open, despite the
global shift in favour of public ownership in the wake of the financial
crisis. The aim is obviously to keep the focus on privatization with
dilution of public control and provision of a greater role for foreign
firms in the insurance sector. This emphasis comes through from the
four principal elements of the current legislative effort. The first
is to permit public insurance companies to mobilize additional money
from the markets. The second is to relax the cap on foreign direct investment
or ownership by foreign players in the insurance sector as a whole.
The third is to reduce the capital requirements for private players
in certain areas, such as the health insurance sector. And the fourth
is to emphasis self-regulation with capital adequacy over structural
regulation of the sector.
In the case of the general insurance sector, besides raising the FDI
cap from 26 to 49 per cent, the relevant bill allows the four state-owned
general insurance companies—Oriental Insurance Company, New India Assurance,
United India Insurance and National Insurance Company—to tap capital
markets for funds after obtaining permission from the government. The
bill also allows insurance companies "to raise newer capital through
newer instruments on the pattern of banks".
Moreover, in a move widely seen as aimed at helping Lloyds of London
in the first instance, the bill seeks to allow foreign re-insurance
companies to open offices and conduct business in the country with a
minimum capital of Rs. 200 crore. Thus far, only the General Insurance
Corporation could provide reinsurance in India. In addition, to make
entry into the rapidly expanding health insurance market easier for
private players, the bill proposes to reduce minimum investment limit
for health insurance companies from Rs. 100 crore to Rs. 50 crore. Also,
the bill seeks to do away with the requirement that promoters have to
divest specified part of their equity after ten years, allowing promoters
to retain control of these corporations. Finally, as part of the new
regulatory framework, a Life Insurance Council and General Insurance
Council are to be set up as self-regulating bodies.
While these are major changes, the big story is what this government
or any version of it that may come to power after the next election
has in store for the Life Insurance Corporation. The Life Insurance
Corporation Amendment Bill is presented as an innocent piece of legislation
aimed at increasing the capital base of LIC, to bring it on par with
private insurers. The problem arises when this is read along with the
changes being pushed through in the general insurance sector. The government
plans to allow government-owned insurance companies to mobilize money
from the capital market, allowing for a dilution of the government’s
shareholding. And this comes along with the decision to raise the cap
on foreign direct investment in the insurance sector from 26 per cent
to 49 per cent. If in time, these provisions are extended to cover the
LIC, the government would recapitalize LIC not with its own money but
with money mobilized from the market and from foreign investors.
This fear stems from the implicit effort to homogenize the insurance
sector, bringing the LIC on par with the private sector. This does signify
a move to accelerate the shift in the form of regulation away from direct
control through public ownership of institutions in the life and general
insurance sectors to self-regulation based on IRDA norms and guidelines
and capital adequacy requirements. The use of capital adequacy is reflected
in the provision in the bill to cap the sovereign guarantee provided
to those insured by the LIC and replacing it with a provision that a
part of the surplus—which is the excess of assets over liabilities actuarially
calculated—must be treated as a solvency margin and placed in a reserve
fund, which the corporation can access in times of need. As of now,
95 per cent of these surpluses are distributed to policy holders as
bonuses and the rest is transferred to the government as dividend against
its Rs. 5 crore investment. The bill provides for the transfer to policyholders
to be capped anywhere between 90 and 95 per cent, with the balance divided
between the government and the reserve fund. Thus, state control and
state guarantee are to be replaced with self regulation, capital adequacy
and solvency margins. This is clearly a sign of long-term intentions.
It should be clear that these bills are aimed at making the insurance
sector private dominated, self-regulated and “competitive”. Is there
a case for such a transition? There is much evidence on the adverse
consequences of such competition and the beneficial effects of government
intervention in the insurance sector. The insurance industry delivers
"products" that are promises to pay, in the form of contracts,
which help lessen the incidence of uncertainty in various spheres. The
insured pays to fully or partially insulate herself from risks such
as an accident, fire, theft or sickness or provide for dependents in
case of death. In theory, to enter such a contract, the insured needs
information regarding the operations of the insurer to whom she pays
in advance large sums in the form of premia, in lieu of a promise that
the latter would meet in full or part the costs of some future event,
the occurrence of which is uncertain. These funds are deployed by the
insurer in investments being undertaken by agents about whose competence
and reliability the policy holder makes a judgment based on the information
she has. The viability of those projects and the returns yielded from
them determine the ability of the insurer to meet the relevant promise.
To the extent that the different kinds of information required are imperfectly
available, the whole business is characterised by a high degree of risk.
This makes excessive competition in insurance a problem. In an effort
to drum up more business and earn higher profits, insurance companies
could underprice their insurance contracts, be cavalier with regard
to the information they seek about policy holders, and be adventurous
when investing their funds by deploying them in high-risk, but high-return
ventures. Not surprisingly, countries where competition is rife in the
insurance industry, such as the US, have been characterised by a large
number of failures. As far back as 1990, a Subcommittee of the US House
of Representatives noted in a report on insurance company insolvencies
revealingly titled "Failed Promises", that a spate of failures,
including those of some leading companies, was accompanied by evidence
of "rapid expansion, overreliance on managing general agents, extensive
and complex reinsurance arrangements, excessive underpricing, reserve
problems, false reports, reckless management, gross incompetence, fraudulent
activity, greed and self-dealing." The committee argued that "the
driving force (of such 'deplorable' management practices) was quick
profits in the short run, with no apparent concern for the long-term
well-being of the company, its policyholders, its employees, its reinsurers,
or the public." The case for stringent regulation of the industry
was obvious and forcefully made.
Things have not changed much since, as the failure and $150 billion
bail-out of global insurance major American International Group (AIG)
in September made clear. AIG was the world’s biggest insurer when assessed
in terms of market capitalisation. It failed because of huge marked-to-market
losses in its financial products division, which wrote insurance on
fixed-income securities held by banks. But these were not straightforward
insurance deals based on due diligence that offered protection against
potential losses. It was a form of investment in search of high returns,
which allowed banks to circumvent regulation and accumulate risky assets.
As the Financial Times (September 17, 2008) noted, “banks that entered
credit default swaps with AIGFP could assure auditors and regulators
that the risk of the underlying asset going bad was protected, and with
a triple A rated counterparty.” That is, AIG used policy-holder money
and debt to invest like an investment bank through its financial products
division. When a lot of its assets turned worthless AIG could not be
let go, because that would have systemic implications. The alternative
was nationalization.
It is in this background that we need to address the question of the
"efficency" of competition from private entrants. To start
with, against the promised private gains in terms of the efficiency
of service providers, we need to compare the potential private loss
in the form of increased risk and the social loss in the form of the
inability of the state as a representative of social interest to direct
investments by the insurance industry. Further, if insolvencies become
the order of the day, there could be private losses as well as social
losses because the state is forced to emerge as the "insurer of
last resort". The losses may far exceed the gains, implying that
the industry should be restructured with the purpose of realising in
full the advantages of public ownership.
Yet India’s government pushes ahead with privatization, despite the
fact that there is no evidence of the nationalised insurance industry
failing on grounds of meeting its obligations either to the insurees
or to the government. The LIC has not merely put at the Government's
disposal large volumes of capital for investment but also addressed
the problems of insurance for the poor. It is not only the global experience
with privatized insurance but the Indian experience with nationalised
insurance that does not seem to matter. In the circumstance, the two
insurance bills appear to be declarations of India's intentions to globalise
further during the current Prime Minister’s tenure, independent of the
consequences for its people.