This should have strengthened the rupee further. That did not happen
because of the RBIıs decision to buy dollars, increase the demand
for that currency and stabilise its value vis-à-vis the rupee. Net
purchases of foreign currency from the market by the Reserve Bank
of India amounted to $3.25 billion between end-March 1999 and end-March
2000. These purchases resulted, among other things, in an increase
in the foreign currency assets of the central bank from $29.5 billion
at the end of 1998-99 to $35.1 billion at the end of 1999-20000. The
large demand for dollars that this intervention by the RBI in foreign
exchange markets resulted in help keep the rupee relatively stable
during financial year 199-2000. In fact, RBI figures show that the
real effective exchange rate of the rupee remained more or less constant
during 1999-2000, though, as argued earlier, some depreciation of
the real effective rate could have helped.
It is this recent history which makes the recent downward movement
in the value of the rupee and the RBIıs knee-jerk reaction to it a
bit surprising. It is indeed true that over the first two months of
1999-2000, for which we have information, while exports have staged
a recovery, imports have grown even faster, resulting in an increase
in the trade deficit relative to the corresponding period of the previous
year. But what has been a more depressing influence on the rupee
are signs that portfolio investments are once again turning negative,
and rapidly so. Net FII investments, which in April stood at $617
million, fell to $111 million in May, and turned negative as of June.
Outflows are estimated at $218 million in June and around $300 million
in July.
It must be noted that net outflows do not reflect a complete loss
of FII interest in India. Rather FII purchases during 2000 have been
fairly high. But so have sales. In the net, these institutional investors
appear to be cashing in their past investments, making some new investments
and diverting the rest to other markets. In particular the strengthening
of interest rates in the US and the recovery of markets elsewhere
in Asia have, according to insiders, resulted in a shift of FII focus
away from India. The point is that this consequence of developments
elsewhere has had a dampening effect on the value of the rupee, which
is perceived as being "overvalued".
From the Reserve Bankıs point of view this should have been fine,
except that given the liberalised nature of financial markets, any
perception that a currency is overvalued and that it is headed downwards
sets off speculation in the currency. The typical form this would
take would be the acquisition of rupees that are used to purchase
dollars, which in turn are later sold for a much larger sum. So long
as this difference is greater than the interest costs incurred on
the original amount at prevailing interest rates, the transaction
yields a profit.
The difficulty is that transactions of this kind by increasing
the demand for dollars, strengthens the dollar relative to the rupee
to an even greater extent, ensuring that speculative expectations
are realised. It is obvious that the RBI, based on past experience,
expected at least some of those authorised to deal in foreign exchange
to behave in this manner. This raises the possibility that a warranted
and welcome depreciation of the rupee can soon turn into collapse,
which can have a host of adverse implications. It is only that perception
that can explain the heavy-handed response of the central bank.
The source of that perception could have been evidence that the RBIıs
strategy of playing the marketı was proving inadequate to stabilise
the rupee. Figure on foreign exchange reserves reveal that the foreign
currency assets of the RBI fell by $1.4 billion between end-March
2000 and mid-July 2000. Sensing a downward pressure on the rupee the
RBI was clearly offloading dollars in the market with the aim of strengthening
the rupee. It was possibly when this proved inadequate to halt an
accelerated slide of the rupee that the decision to reverse the direction
of monetary policy was taken.
It is to be expected that industry would be affected adversely by
the hike in interest rates and the squeeze in liquidity, since it
occurs at a time when industrial growth still remains sluggish and
the demand for consumer durables has weakened. This only suggests
once again that financial liberalisation, which makes monetary and
fiscal policy the victim of the whims of highly mobile and speculative
portfolio investors, is in the long run inimical to the development
of the real, commodity producing sectors. But there is more to learn
from these developments. It also makes clear that the defence of financial
reform on the grounds that it would help create an autonomous central
bank and increase the effectiveness of monetary policy is completely
misplaced. The size of the foreign currency assets of the RBI, which
is a crucial influence on money supply, is clearly determined by the
whimsical behaviour of the foreign financial investor. And there are
times when adjustments in the foreign assets position of the central
bank is inadequate to realise an objective, necessitating changes
in crucial parameters determining the central bankıs monetary stance.
This renders all talk of autonomy of the central bank meaningless.
While the central bank in India may have won a degree of independence
from the scrutiny and influence of the executive and, more crucially,
of Parliament, it now appears to have subordinated itself to the requirements
of international finance. It is not autonomy that has been won, but
a new master.