Given this prospect it is surprising that the policy
initiatives announced by the government recently seem to
focus only on the farmer. To start with, resources from
the Calamity Relief Fund, which was created at the
instance of the Eleventh Finance Commission and has at
its disposal Rs. 11,000 crore over a five-year period,
are to be used for financing relief work. But the nature
of such relief work has not been defined. Further, the
fact that in a statement to the press the Minister for
Agriculture has said that these resources are going to
be made available to all farmers in drought hit
districts and not just small and marginal farmers is
revealing. It fails to mention the agricultural worker
whose plight is likely to be severely affected.
Most of the other proposed measures are directly aimed
at farmers. Nabard is to be instructed to defer recovery
of interest on crop loans, and there is a small
probability that interest dues may be waived altogether.
Guidelines are to be issued to sugar mills to pay out
arrears due to cane growers. And deferred payment of
insurance premia under the National Agricultural
Insurance Scheme is to be condoned.
The problem is that, besides ignoring the huge
proportion of the rural population with limited or no
assets, this partial, and yet to be implemented,
response fails to engage the three most important
bottlenecks to any successful management of the
consequences of drought. The first is the inadequate
reach of the public distribution system in most states,
especially in the rural areas, which makes the sheer
task of reaching food to those who would need it
daunting. In fact, government policy over the last few
years has moved in the direction of diluting the system
rather than strengthening and expanding it. As a result
the government would have to reach its stocks to the
needy through the private trade, which is bound to
resort to speculative hoarding, since prices are
expected to rise in a situation like this. This makes
the presence of large stocks in government godowns an
inadequate insurance against both localised shortages as
well as price increases.
The second is the fact that the government's stocks do
not contain significant amounts of the commodities in
whose case the shortfall in output is likely to be the
largest. While the availability of large foreign
exchange reserves with the government facilitates import
of these commodities, this would have to be through the
private trade route in the current liberalised trading
environment. Here again private speculative activity is
bound to drive up prices.
The third is the government's aversion on fiscal grounds
to launching a massive food-for-work programme, and
therefore its lack of experience in managing such a
programme. It is almost common knowledge now that a
phenomenon like drought can be devastating not so much
because of the lack of access to food supplies but
because of the lack of the requisite employment and
income that allows people to purchase the food that is
available. Over the last few years when evidence was
mounting that foodstocks were accumulating in government
godowns even while poverty was persisting at relatively
high levels and reports of starvation were flowing in
from parts of the country, there were many who made a
case for using the food surpluses as a means to launch a
more extensive food-for-work programme that would
provide employment and incomes to the poor as well
stimulate demand for an industrial sector which was
burdened with excess capacity.
If the government had not ignored these calls on the
grounds that it was not a fiscally prudent strategy to
adopt, it would have been in a position to quickly
respond to the income reduction-induced threat of near
famine conditions. Not having responded, however, it
would, even if it tries, be hard put to set up and
manage such a large exercise in time to avert any
significant human damage.
These bottlenecks to dealing effectively with the
consequences of drought are already having their impact.
Quite early into the monsoon season, expectations of
monsoon failure have triggered an increase in the prices
of many agricultural commodities, stocks and foreign
exchange reserves with the government notwithstanding.
To quote one example, in the Mumbai wholesale market,
the price of groundnut oil spurted from Rs 420 per 10 kg
trading lot on July 6 to Rs 438 by July 13. Refined
palmolein gained Rs 17 during the same period to close
at Rs 347 and refined soybean oil jumped from Rs 330 to
Rs 346 per 10 kg. On July 15, groundnut oil jumped
further by Rs 10 to Rs 448 and palmolein by Rs. 11 to Rs
358.
Meanwhile governments in the affected states are sensing
the danger of loss of employment among the large mass of
workers who are either partially or completely dependent
on wage employment for a living. Not surprisingly, they
have approached the Centre for a combination of food and
cash support for relief and food-for-work programmes.
Andhra Pradesh for example has asked for Rs 610 crore by
way of financial assistance and 10 lakh tonnes of food
grains for the purpose. While a "centre-friendly" state
like AP is likely to get a quick response, past
experience suggests that Delhi would be far less
receptive to demands from many other states, making the
rural workers and farmers the victim of cynical
political strategies.
Thus, three immediate outcomes are likely, unless the
monsoon recovers sharply. First, a decline in farmers'
incomes as a result of loss of production and livestock.
Second, the loss of agricultural workers' livelihoods as
a result of the contraction in rural wage employment.
Third, a sharp increase in food prices, as a result of
speculation encouraged by the limited reach of the
government's public distribution system as a means of
reaching food to the poor, especially in the rural
areas. Since, for reasons elaborated earlier, the
government's efforts to counter these tendencies can
only work partially, any further failure of the monsoon
can be devastating.
The second-order fall-out of the
decline in incomes and rise in food prices would be a
sharp erosion in the real purchasing power of a large
section of the population and a greater reticence on the
part of the government to undertake expenditures that
can aggravate the inflation. Both of these are bound to
squeeze the demand for manufactures. Thus an
intensification of the recession, which already afflicts
the industrial sector, could ensue.
Thus the complacence, reflected in official statements,
generated by the government's huge food stocks and large
foreign exchange reserves is by no means warranted. But
such complacence clearly dominates, encouraged by the
tendency to see in the drought an opportunity to offload
the embarrassingly large stocks of foodgrain in
government godowns. |