Discussions
of GDP growth at both national and international levels often get carried
away by relatively recent trends. But it is sometime useful to situate
recent income growth in the longer term context, if only to remind ourselves
of the structural processes involved.
It is also useful because the second half of the twentieth century is
generally perceived as the most dynamic in the history of capitalism.
It is also seen as a period in which at least some developing countries
managed to improve their relative position in the global income hierarchy,
in different phases and through different trajectories.
There are various ways in which this is supposed to have occurred. Import
substituting industrialisation in the 1950s and 1960s played a role in
diversifying large developing and thereby generating a higher rate of
GDP growth. Oil exporting countries benefited from the oil price increases
of the second half of the 1970s, which enabled some of them top move to
a higher level of per capita income. According to some analysts, the most
recent "globalisation" phase of the 1990s has enabled some countries
– China and India in particular – to benefit from more open global trade
and thereby increase per capita incomes and reduce poverty.
All this would presumably have operated to create more convergence of
incomes between the developed and developing worlds, even if in fits and
starts, such that the gap between per capita incomes of countries across
the world would start reducing. While this can and has been examined with
econometric analyses of varying degrees of sophistication, it is also
possible to just look at the overall evidence on GDP growth patterns from
different sources.
Table 1 provides evidence on shares of various regions over the period
1950-1998, of global population and global GDP re-estimated according
to Purchasing Power Parity (PPP). These are based on data provided in
an OECD study by Angus Maddison (Angus Maddison: The World Economy: A
Millenial Perspective, OECD Paris 2001).
PPP estimates are used instead of nominal exchange rates to compare income
across economies, because of the widely observed reality that currencies
command different purchasing power in different countries, than is suggested
by the nominal rates. However, there are some well-known problems in the
estimates of income using exchange rates based on PPP, not least of which
are the issues of choosing comparable baskets of goods and the poor quality
of the data on actual prices prevailing in different countries (including
large developing countries such as China and India) that are used in such
studies, which affect the reliability of such calculations.
There is a less talked about but equally significant conceptual problem
with using PPP estimates. In general, countries that have high PPP, that
is where the actual purchasing power of the currency is deemed to be much
higher than the nominal value, are typically low-income countries with
low average wages. It is precisely because there is a significant section
of the workforce that receives very low remuneration, that goods and services
are available cheaply. Therefore, using PPP-modified GDP data may miss
the point, by seeing as an advantage the very feature that reflects greater
poverty of the majority of wage earners in that economy.
Nevertheless, PPP-based estimates have been widely used, even though they
are likely to overestimate incomes of working people in lower-income countries
for the reasons described above. Maddison's estimates, presented in Table
1, allow us to track the relative population and income shares by broad
category of country for the latter half of the 20th century.
Table
1: Shares
of global population and income in PPP terms |
|
Percent share of world population |
Per cent share of world output in PPP terms |
Developed
Countries |
1950 |
19 |
57 |
1973 |
15.6 |
50.9 |
1998 |
12.1 |
45.6 |
Developing Countries |
1950 |
70.4 |
30 |
1973 |
75.2 |
36.1 |
1998 |
81 |
49 |
Eastern
Europe and Former USSR |
1950 |
10.6 |
13.1 |
1973 |
9.2 |
12.8 |
1998 |
6.9 |
5.4 |
Source: Angus
Maddison (2001) |
It is evident that, as far as the countries that were known as "developed"
in 1950 are concerned, there has been relatively little change in the
per capita income position vis-a-vis the rest of the world, especially
since the mid-1970s. In 1950 the developed countries received nearly
60 per cent of global income, but they also accounted for almost 20
per cent of world population. In the twenty five years after 1973, the
share of the income of the developed countries fell by only 10 per cent,
or 5.3 percentage points, whereas the share of population declined by
22 per cent or 3.5 percentage points. So even in PPP terms, just above
one-tenth of global population in the developed countries still receives
nearly half the world's income.
Consider the same ratios for the developing countries taken as a group.
This category includes all the “success stories” of the developing world
in East Asia and elsewhere, the socialist countries outside of Eastern
Europe and the former USSR as well as several oil-exporting countries
that have benefited from global oil price booms. There has been some
improvement in global income shares for this group as a whole, but this
has been far outpaced by the growing share of the developing world in
global population. So, between 1950 and 1998 developing countries managed
to increase their share of global income by 15 per cent, or nearly 11
percentage points, their share of global population increased by a whopping
63 per cent, or 19 percentage points, so that there was no relative
increase in per capita terms.
The countries of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe have typically
been treated as outside of both these categories, and it is interesting
to note how this process worked out for these countries. Between 1950
and 1973, the conditions appeared broadly stable, that is, there was
a slight decline in both population and global GDP shares. However,
after 1973 – or more accurately, probably after 1989 and the collapse
of the Berlin Wall – there has been a sharp decline in population share
(35 per cent, or 4 percentage points), associated with an even sharper
decline in income share (59 per cent, or 8 percentage points).
Given all the problems of basing inter-country income comparisons on
PPP estimates, it is worth looking at comparisons based on nominal exchange
rates, which do provide some idea of inter-country income differentials
especially in a world in which trade penetration is increasing. Chart
1 provides the evidence on per capita incomes across some major countries
and country groupings for the period 1960-2006, based on the World Bank’s
World Development Indicators.
This chart shows very clearly how large the global income gaps are.
The initial differences in per capita incomes (in 1960 in this case)
were so large that even quite rapid increases in per capita incomes
in some regions over the subsequent four and half decades have not managed
to make the gap more repsectable. Thus, while the per capita income
of the fastest growing developing region – East Asia – increased by
more than ten times over this period compared to an increase of less
than three times for the US, in 2006, the average income for US was
still fifteen times that of East Asia.
For other developing regions the per capita income gaps have been even
larger and in some cases growing. Thus, the per capita GDP in the current
Euro area in 1960 was 34 times that of South Asia; but by 2006, it had
increased to 36 times. For Sub-Saharan Africa, the widening gap was
even more stark. In 1960, the per capita income of the countries that
are now in the Euro Area was 15 times that of Sub-Saharan Africa; by
2006, the difference was as large as 38 times.
Latin America was then and remains the richest developing region, yet
the per capita income gaps between it and both the US and the EU have
increased in the past forty six years. Even for countries in the Middle
East and North Africa, which contains several major oil exporters, the
income gaps have grown substantially with respect to both the US and
the Euro Area countries.
Another way of examining this is to look at the share of countries or
regions in world GDP in dollar terms, rather than in PPP terms. It turns
out that at nominal exchange rates, the share of developing countries,
even the largest and most dynamic ones, remains quite puny. Even in
the first six years of this century, after more than two decades of
rapid growth in China and India, the two countries account for less
than 7 per cent of global GDP compared to 30 per cent for the US (changed
relatively little from the 1960s) and 14 per cent for Japan. The share
of China, India, Brazil and Argentina together in 2000-06 was less than
10 per cent.
This pattern is at least partly because the growth performance of the
developing world has been so uneven. Within the developing world, only
East Asia and the Pacific and South Asia show any significant acceleration
of growth since the 1960s or indeed higher growth rates than the developing
world. Furthermore, it is evident that for South Asia the acceleration
is relatively recent, so it is really only East Asia and the Pacific
that in the aggregate has shown rapid growth over a prolonged period.
The other developing regions showed higher growth rates during the import
substitution phase, and do not appear to have benefited much from the
"globalisation" phase in GDP growth terms. If the 1980s was
a "lost decade" for Latin America, with declines in real GDP,
the subsequent decade was not much better, especially given the low
base. Even the recent spurt has led to average growth rates of less
than 2 per cent per annum. Meanwhile Sub-Saharan Africa has experienced
two lost decades, with average real GDP (in aggregate, not per capita
terms) falling continuously in the 1980s and the 1990s.
So the picture of a very dynamic and rapidly changing world economy,
in which developing countries are emerging as the major players, may
be overplayed. A longer term perspective on growth suggests that for
much of the developing world, relative positions in the international
economy have hardly changed at all.
|