After
being off the radar of public attention for long, the mining industry
in India is now in focus. For example, the controversies surrounding
the Posco and Vedanta projects in Orissa, involving the acquisition
of large tracts of land for mining purposes, had drawn attention to
the damage to livelihoods and ecology that mining could result in. More
recently in distant Karnataka, allegations of the collusion between
mining interests and politicians in power, leading to large and not
always legitimate profits garnered at the expense of the local people
and the state exchequer, has led to the resignation of the state's ombudsman.
The mining sector is increasingly seen as one in which the worst features
of capitalism as a profit machine combine with illegality and corruption
to provide a site for primitive accumulation based on plunder and unequal
exchange.
This is only partly because mining has delivered fortunes to those private
interests which after economic liberalisation have been able to find
a foothold in the industry. The industry has also drawn attention because
mining areas have become the sites of violent political opposition to
both private capital and the state. Analyses of the reasons for these
developments point in many directions. Displacement, loss of traditional
livelihoods of tribal populations and ecological destruction are, of
course, prime among them. In addition, in some regions and states mining
interests from ''outside'' reportedly rule the areas they exploit by
maintaining private armies or by entering parliamentary politics to
win influence and control the administration of mining areas and the
framing and implementation of mining policy. Power at one pole, especially
if violently exercised, generates dissent and opposition at the other,
which too can turn violent.
This kind of ''carpetbagger capitalism'' in which wealth accumulation
by ''outsiders'' who extract mineral resources occurs at the expense
of local populations, whose traditional habitat and means of livelihood
are damaged, is not specific to mining in India. It is true of all locations
where the state has either not regulated mining firms or interests or
has even worked in their favour when resources are being mined. Mineral
resources are non-reproducible and therefore the duration for which
they can be exploited is limited, and the returns from mining dwindle
as the best quality ores and the most accessible strains are exhausted.
On the other hand, for geological reasons, individual mineral resources
are concentrated in particular regions of the world and in specific
areas within those regions and nations. Rising global demand, irrespective
of where it emanates from, therefore encourages the quick exploitation
of available mineral resources from a few locations.
The difficulty is that in most cases mining, which requires ''extracting''
the resource, is destructive of the environment in which it occurs.
Large swathes of land have to be excavated. If the area was forested
it has to be cleared. If it was inhabited, the local population has
to be relocated and rehabilitated. If water is required for mining purposes,
local water sources must be drained. And if the process of mining releases
toxic material, ecological and human damage through pollution of various
kinds would occur, unless efforts are made to collect those materials
and put them to use or dispose of them safely.
The dimensions of the problem are not easy to understand. Consider the
situation in India, for example. Taking a national view, mining does
not seem to be an overwhelmingly important activity in the country.
The mining and quarrying sector currently contributes only around 2
per cent to India's GDP. Further, more than 60 per cent of this value
is due to fuels, a significant share of which is produced offshore,
away from human habitation. Offshore areas accounted for 18 per cent
of the value of mineral production in 2009-10. (Though, this seems to
shift the problem away from where it affects us humans, the BP spill
should remind us that even this is not true.) The resulting seemingly
minimal economic relevance of mining conflicts with the role it increasingly
plays in generating discontent and opposition within the country.
However, the reasons why mining areas are the sites for political conflict
are many. To start with, where the adverse effects of mining are inadequately
remedied, the consequences for the affected can be dire. Secondly, though
according to the Ministry of Mines, India produces as many as 86 minerals,
a few minerals account for a dominant share of non-fuel mineral production.
These include coal, lignite and bauxite (in which India ranked third
among the world's producers in 2007-08), iron ore (fourth) and manganese
(fifth). Moreover, these resources are concentrated in a few contiguous
areas. During 2009-10, while mineral production was reported from 32
States and Union Territories, among onshore areas a few states dominated:
Andhra Pradesh (with a 12.24% share in production by value), Orissa
(11.85%), Chhattisgarh (9.18%) and Jharkhand (8.79%). Together with
the offshore areas they account for 60 per cent of mineral production
by value. They also are home to large tribal populations. And they are
among the states where violent political movements are on the rise.
It is nobody's case that no mining should occur. The case is clearly
for restricting the extent of mining keeping in mind the common good
and taking account of both immediate and long-term costs and returns.
In fact, almost everybody swears by certain principles. While different
mineral resources should be exploited to differing degrees given technological
options and the benefits from production using mineral raw materials,
the effort should be to minimize the social costs. Ecologically-sensitive
areas should not be mined. Deforestation should be kept to a minimum.
Compensation, relocation and rehabilitation must be organised in ways
which are fair. And pollution should be minimal after abatement.
However, recognising all this is not enough. There must be laws, institutions
and processes in place which ensure that decisions with regard to the
extent and means of mineral extraction in different locations should
be taken in ways that ensures social participation, especially of those
who would be adversely affected. The fact of the matter is that while
lip service is paid to such institutions and processes, they do not
work in this country (and in many others in the world as well). In fact,
the complex division of labour between the central and state governments
with regard to the framing and implementation of mining policy obfuscates
accountability to a substantial degree, only worsening matters.
This has in recent years become more of a problem because of the ways
in which the post-1991 policy of economic liberalisation and ''reform''
have affected the mining sector. As noted above, mining is an area where
most costs are social and fall heavily on those not directly involved
in mineral extraction. If in such an environment, private producers
operating purely for profit are given an important role, it generates
the classic situation where private and social returns diverge substantially,
especially when private returns are high and social costs are not required
to be compensated for.
This situation is relatively recent in India's post-Independence history.
During much of that period mining was largely a preserve of the state.
Under the Industrial Policy Resolution, 1956, the mining of major minerals
such as coal, lignite, mineral oils, iron ore, copper, zinc and atomic
minerals, was made the exclusive preserve of the public sector. It was
only in the extraction of minor minerals that the private sector was
allowed along with the public sector. As a result, much of mining occurred
within the ambit of the public sector. Even today, the public sector
continues to play a dominant role in mineral production accounting for
more than 70% of the total value of production.
It is of course true that the operations of the public sector too resulted
in displacement, ecological damage and loss of traditional livelihood
opportunities. But with the public sector under managements which were
accountable to parliament, the degree to which it could ignore social
costs was limited. Moreover, with the public sector not under pressure
to privilege profit above all else, it was in a position to provide
for compensation, rehabilitation and abatement. The system was not inherently
biased towards discounting the social costs of mining operations. Under
that regime, therefore, the problem was largely one of inadequate investment
to effectively and safely exploit the mineral resources of the country.
In fact, even when shortages in some areas encouraged small-scale illegal
mining, it was often more in the nature of petty production, sustained
of course by the presence and exploitation of large trading capital.
Matters began to change in the 1990s, with the post-liberalisation shift
to the National Mineral Policy of March 1993. Designed to encourage
private investment in exploration and mining, the policy opened up thirteen
major minerals-iron ore, manganese ore, chrome ore, sulphur, gold, diamond,
copper, lead, zinc, molybdenum, tungsten, nickel, and platinum-hitherto
reserved exclusively for the public sector for private investment. Further,
the policy expressly provided for foreign technology and foreign participation
in exploration and mining. Initially, Foreign Direct Investment was
allowed, subject to clearance by the Foreign Investment Promotion Board
(FIPB), up to 50 per cent of equity (with no limit for captive mines).
However, additional FDI holding was provided for on a case-by-case basis.
In 1997, FDI up to 50 per cent was taken out of the purview of the FIPB
and put on automatic approval route and in February 2006, FDI up to
100 per cent was permitted in mining.
Though the initial response to liberalisation was lukewarm, there has
been a rush of investment into the area in recent years. According to
an estimate made by the Indian Institute of Metals in 2009, a sum close
to $300 billion is expected to be invested in the metals and mining
sectors in eastern India over the next few years. This is six times
the aggregate investment made since Independence. Much of this investment
is to occur in the mineral rich states of Orissa and Jharkhand followed
by Chhattisgarh and West Bengal.
The government has been arguing that this liberalisation, introduced
to attract much-needed investment into the mining sector, has been accompanied
by new rules, guidelines and measures to ensure that the benefits are
fairly distributed. The opposition and civil society activists on the
other hand argue that there is no tooth to whatever legislation is in
place and little commitment to implementing many of the regulations
that are indeed available. The state is most often seen as colluding
with private operators to further the latter's interests at the expense
of local populations.
As result, argue critics, in a state like Orissa, the rapid pace of
mineral exploitation has contributed little to the development of the
state. According to a study by Banikanta Mishra (Economic & Political
Weekly, May 15, 2010), during the post-liberalisation period from 1993-94
to 2003-04, the extent of mineral exploitation has increased by 10.3%
per year, with the value of minerals extracted rising at 12.8% per annum.
Much of this was for export, with the quantity of mineral exported out
of the state rising by 15.7% per year. On the other hand, the number
of workers employed in mining had been falling by 4% annually, even
while ecological damage and livelihood loss was worsening standards
of living.
That there is basis for such cynicism is illustrated by the delay in
formulating and approving appropriate alternative legislation to replace
the Mines and Minerals (Development and Regulation) Act of 1957. The
Ministry of Mines is pushing for legislation that mandates, among other
things, the sharing of profits from mining with the local population
and the state government. The new law seeks to make sharing of at least
26 per cent of profits with the local population mandatory. According
to reports, the law ministry influenced by other sections in government
is opposed to these changes. Union mines minister, B.K. Handique, who
has been quite vocal on the matter, has reportedly received no response
to his efforts to get the draft legislation cleared and taken to parliament.
Clearly then, the ethos of liberalisation that privileges private sector
production and celebrates profit-making is one in which an appropriate
mining policy would prove difficult to formulate, let alone implement.
Public control over mining rights and mining activity in the pre-liberalisation
period was not driven by socialistic motives, but by the recognition
that a sustainable mining strategy cannot be evolved when the activity
is privately undertaken. The retreat from an interventionist policy,
the evidence suggests, delivers the kind of outcomes that enhances the
wealth of some while increasing the deprivation of the majority in India's
mining belts leading to violent forms of protest. The message is clear.
Liberalisation is not a means of increasing the efficiency of the system.
It is a policy that facilitates a process of primitive accumulation
that leads to social disruption.