There
was a time when global oil prices reflected changes in real demand
and supply of crude petroleum. Of course, as with many other primary
commodities, the changes in the market could be volatile, and so
prices also fluctuated, sometimes sharply. More than any other commodity,
the global oil market was seen to reflect not only current economic
conditions and perceptions of future activity, but also geopolitical
changes and cross-currents.
Ever since the early 1970s, when group of some major oil exporting
countries OPEC, forced a three-fold increase in global oil prices
its shadow has loomed large. There is still widespread perception
that the cartel of oil-exporting countries can manipulate and influence
the price by changing the level of their own supplies. As a result,
even oil-exporting countries that are not members of the cartel
have benefited from OPEC's decisions about supply, since they have
also been beneficiaries of rising oil prices.
But in fact, OPEC is more like a club of a minority of oil producers,
rather than a cartel that is in command of world oil supply. It
controls less than 40 per cent of world oil production, compared
to 70 per cent in the early 1970s. Non-OPEC countries account for
increasingly significant proportions of global supply: Russia has
overtaken Saudi Arabia as the largest supplier of crude oil since
2009. Partly as a result of this, OPEC has recently been quite inefficient
in imposing any kind of production quota on its members, who have
happily increased or decreased their production as they wished.
Most of its members are producing exactly as they would if OPEC
did not exist.
Indeed, for the past two decades, OPEC's role has generally been
more towards price stabilisation rather than pushing for increases,
and it may even have played a moderating role in oil markets, including
when particular events such as political disruptions in major exporting
countries caused sudden supply shortfalls. OPEC formerly abandoned
its declared price band in 2005, and since then has been largely
powerless in determining prices.
The argument that rising demand from China and India has determined
the upward trend in global oil prices is also unjustified. While
these two countries (and particularly China) do account for growing
(but still small) shares of global demand, these increases have
been counterbalanced from slower demand from other regions of the
world, including the US and Europe. As a consequence, on average,
global oil demand has continued to grow at between 1 and 2 per cent
per annum over the past five years, usually at a rate slightly below
the annual rate of increase in global oil production.
Recent price changes in global oil markets are increasingly affected
by other forces, which have more to do with financial speculation
and expectations than with current movements in demand and supply.
Chart 1 indicates the extent of the recent rise, and shows how much
it mirrors the earlier rise in oil prices between January 2007 and
June 2008.
This confirms the points made earlier about the role of other factors
in global oil markets. Clearly, this extent of price volatility
– with dramatic rise, fall and rise again within the space of three
years - cannot be the result of real demand and supply changes.
Despite this, most mainstream media persist in trying to isolate
some factors affecting production in particular locations, to account
for the price changes.
The ongoing crisis in the Middle East – and particularly Libya –
is generally believed to be the impetus behind the latest spurt
in prices. But Libya produces less than 3 per cent of global petroleum
output, and Saudi Arabia (whose current excess stocks are already
more than annual production in Libya and Algeria) has already made
up current shortfalls and promised to compensate for any future
shortfall. Since the unrest in the Arab region began, there has
been no significant change in global oil production, which continues
to average around 88 million barrels per day.
In any case, currently global spare oil capacity is closer to historic
highs than to historic lows. Proven reserves of oil amount to more
than 40 years worth of global consumption at current levels – the
highest such ratio in the past thirty years.
The current price spike is therefore not the result of demand and
supply imbalances but is driven by uncertainty, rumour and speculative
financial activity in oil futures markets. Even in terms of expectations,
Libya is only part of the problem (and in fact oil production still
continues in many Libyan facilities despite the civil war). The
concern in financial markets may be more about the potential endgame
if the unrest spreads to Saudi Arabia. But the increase in oil prices
is happening well before such a drama actually plays out, and before
any serious disruption to global supply.
It is therefore likely that the rapid increases in oil price and
the associated price volatility over the past year in particular,
are largely driven by purely financial activity. This is very similar
to the effects of financial speculation on other commodity markets
such as food items. The volume of trading in crude oil futures contracts
has expanded dramatically over the past decade. As noted by Robert
Pollin and James Heintz (''How speculation is affecting gasoline
prices today'', Americans for Financial Reform mimeo, July 2011),
the overall level of futures market trading of crude oil contracts
on the New York Mercantile Exchange is currently 400 percent greater
than it was in 2001, and 60 percent higher than it was two years
ago. Even relative to the increases in the physical production of
global oil supplies, trading is still 300 percent greater today
than it was in 2001, and 33 percent greater than two years previously.
The ratio of ''open interest'' contracts of NYMEX (New York Metals
Exchange) crude oil futures to total global oil production is one
useful indicator of the growing extent of speculative activity in
this market. This ratio was between 4-6 per cent in the first half
of the 2000s, increased to 12 per cent in late 2006 and then to
as much as 18 per cent just before the oil price peaked in June
2008. It then fell to 13 per cent in the middle of 2008, as oil
prices fell. It has been mostly rising since then, with average
levels of 16 per cent in the past few months. Large traders in particular
show growing volumes of ''long'' positions that anticipate future
price increases. (Data from Commodity Futures Trading Commission
website www.cftc.gov
accessed 6 July 2011).
While this explains some of the recent volatility witnessed in oil
prices, there are some other more puzzling features of the recent
price increases. Earlier, the three major forms of crude petroleum
in the global market – Brent Crude, West Texas Intermediate and
Dubai crude – generally showed similar if not identical prices.
If anything, the price of West Texas Intermediate oil used to be
slightly higher because of perceived better quality and lower sulphur
content.
However, in the very recent past the prices have diverged, and as
Chart 2 shows, West Texas Intermediate is now the lowest of the
three prices. By the middle of June the difference was more than
$22 per barrel. It is not fully clear what is causing this deviation,
especially the increasing extent of it. But it is also true that
futures market activity is greater for both Brent and Dubai crude
oil.
We
all know who loses from rising oil prices: most of us. Oil prices
directly and indirectly enter into all other prices, through higher
fuel costs of production and transport. Agriculture is directly
affected, so food prices will definitely rise further with this
oil price increase, worsening the resurgent food crisis. Such cost
pressures have another consequence: they push governments to inflation
control measures, such as higher interest rates. In many countries
this worsens the chances for the already fragile economic recovery
after the crisis. So people across the world face lower real incomes
and may face reduced employment opportunities.
Oil-importing developing countries tend to get hit much worse than
other oil importers. First, the energy-intensity of output is still
much higher (twice on average) than production in OECD countries.
Second, developing countries are often more foreign exchange-constrained
and so high oil import bills lead to balance of payments difficulties.
The poorest countries are usually the worst affected, and within
developing countries poorer groups take the brunt of the impact
in higher costs of living and lower wage prospects.
So the doubling of the oil price that we have seen in the past year
has already destroyed any positive effects of foreign aid that oil-importing
developing countries receive. Since it is also linked to global
food prices the negative effects are compounded for food importing
countries. During the last such price peak in 2008, there were calls
for compensatory financing to be provided to oil and food importers
by the IMF. This never came about, but this time round we have not
even heard such noises, certainly not loudly enough.
Who gains from the rising oil prices? The conventional approach
is to look at the countries that are major oil exporters, and somehow
assume that they are the beneficiaries of such price spikes, and
that this leads to a redistribution of global income away from oil-importing
to oil-exporting countries. This approach is reinforced by the media,
which keeps emphasising the windfall gains of governments in oil
exporting countries.
But this misses the point. The really big gainers – accounting for
the largest portion of the gains by far – are the big oil companies.
In fact, big oil, which suffered a setback during the Great Recession,
is back with a bang, riding on the back of the recovery in petroleum
prices in 2010. The major oil companies that announced their results
in January 2011 reported a doubling of profits in 2010 compared
to the previous year. The three big US companies ExxonMobil, Chevron
and ConocoPhillips together had nearly $60 billion profits after
all costs and taxes. The profits of the Anglo-Dutch company Royal
Dutch Shell also doubled, even though production was lower than
expected.
Why do profits of big oil companies increase so much during periods
of high or rising oil prices? Basically, the costs per barrel of
the companies reflect their historical costs of drilling, exploration
and/or purchase of crude oil, which often have little or nothing
to do with current crude prices. But they are quick to pass on current
crude oil prices to consumers in the form of higher prices for their
products. By contrast, they tend to be much more lethargic about
passing on lower crude prices in the form of lower prices of processed
oil. So increases in crude oil prices lead to enormous windfall
gains for these companies.
In the current price surge, therefore, the real (and maybe only)
gainers are financial speculators in oil futures markets and the
big oil companies that can pass on much more than their own costs
in the form of much higher prices due to the general sense of frenzy
in oil markets. So the case for immediate and substantial taxes
on the windfall oil profits of multinational companies is very compelling.
And so is the case for much more far-reaching and effective regulation
and control of the speculative activity in oil futures and other
commodity markets that is currently causing so much collateral damage.
*This article was originally published in
the Frontline, Vol.: 28, No. 15, July 16-29, 2011.