The
focus of the government's privatisation drive has shifted to the civil
aviation sector. In a move aimed at scorching rumours of dissension
within the cabinet regarding its "big ticket" privatisation
drive, the Prime Minister reportedly convened, towards the end of
May, a meeting of the Cabinet Committee on Disinvestment. That meeting
arrived at what amounts to the most far-reaching decision as yet with
regard to the nature and thrust of the privatisation process under
the BJP-led regime. The government, it was decided, would offload
up to 60 percent of its stake in India¹s national flag carrier, Air
India. Of this 26 per cent would be offered to a strategic partner
who could be from abroad, another 14 per cent to a domestic strategic
partner, 10 per cent to the financial institutions and other domestic
investors and the remaining10 per cent to employees of the company.
Strategic sales of public assets, as defined by the government, are
aimed at handing over the management of the company to the private
sector. Thus, the move clearly expects an alliance of some kind between
interested foreign investors and domestic private investors who, together,
would control 40 per cent of the equity in the company after privatisation.
Needless to say, in such a tie-up, the foreign investor, who controls
the largest block of equity, other than for the government divesting
managerial responsibility, would be the determining influence on the
operations of the privatised company. A shareholders agreement, to
be negotiated as part of the sale, would ostensibly define the relative
roles of the strategic investors and the government, which through
its own shareholding and that of the financial institutions would
still be in control of 50 per cent of equity in the company. As if
to allay fears that the government had set the scheme up for a take
over of management by foreign investors, the Minister for Disinvestment,
Arun Jaitley, issued a clarification. The scheme, he said, allows
for the possibility of a domestic investor acquiring up to 40 per
cent of equity, provided it had the resources and the technical skills
to run the company along competitive lines..
The decision on Air India comes in the wake of an earlier decision
to divest 51 per cent in the dominantly domestic carrier Indian Airlines,
with 26 per cent being offered to a single buyer who, once again,
would be handed over the management of the company. The somewhat delayed
appointment of a global advisor in the case of Indian Airlines and
the appointment of a similar advisor in the case of Air India are
to occur soon. This would allow the government to complete the process
and garner a part of the Rs. 10,000 crore from disinvestment targeted
for in the Budget for 2000-01, well before the March-end deadline.
These decisions are indeed surprising for a number of reasons. Most
nations have sought to create, and still maintain, a state-owned national
carrier (or carriers) flying international and domestic routes on
strong economic and social grounds. Principal among these are the
need to ensure adequate flights connecting the country concerned to
the major airline hubs of the world and the need to connect different
centres within the country, even if operating such connections are
not in the first instance profitable. International connnectivity
and ease of access is crucial especially when a country is attempting
to engage international markets and build commercial bridges with
the rest of the world. And integration and development without excessive
regional inequality very often requires ensuring transportation and
communication networks, which in themselves may not be profitable
but yield substantial external benefits. In sum, state ownership in
the airline industry may be essential from the developmental¹
point of view of ensuring connectivity across points between which
traffic is low. This is achieved by cross-subsidising unprofitable
operations with revenues from more lucrative routes and even accepting
an overall deficit which is financed through taxation. A form of support
for such cross-subsidisation is the provision of a captive market.
Since the various arms of government are themselves major clients
on international and domestic routes, diverting that traffic to the
state-owned carrier ensures a minimum of revenue along profitable
routes, besides reducing foreign exchange outgo from the country.
Thus, privatisation of the airline sector, which does away with state
control and state support and leaves the decision of which points
to connect and at what frequency to be determined purely by the profit
motive, can result in economically and socially damaging results in
the long run.
It need not be true at all that the indifferent financial performance
of India¹s publicly owned airline companies arises purely from the
social role they have hitherto been called upon to play on these grounds.
Part of the reason their financial bottom line is disappointing may
indeed be a combination of poor management and excessive governmental
intervention. But privatisation as a means to trim the fat is by no
means the best answer. To start with, instances where privately-owned
firms make erroneous investments decisions or manage companies poorly
are legion. The recent experience with private entry into the domestic
airlines sector itself is indicative, with many players such as Modiluft
and NEPC having burnt their fingers and exited at considerable private
and social loss. Further, it is yet unclear how much fat there is
to trim in the existing operation of the two airlines.
But private acquirers of Indian Airlines and Air India need not rely
just on improvements in productivity in existing routes to improve
profitability. They can exploit the opportunity to eat into the "social
routes" when either there is not enough fat to trim or when they
are new unable to cut the existing fat in the state-owned airlines. That is privatisation may just be a process of transforming what
where social gains or benefits into private profits. The latter
may be inevitable given the high returns which are expected by private
investors based on hypothetical calculations of profits foregone by
choosing this rather then some other lucrative area of investment.
It should be obvious that any effort by the government to use the
its own residual shareholding and the shareholders agreement with
the likely private investors as a means of preventing the transformation
of social benefits into private profits would be subverted. Given
the logic of private calculations of the opportunity costs of investing
in the airlines sector, any attempt at restricting profit maximising
tendencies would make the exercise of privatising airlines one more
instance of the failed experiments with privatisation in recent years.
It is this aspect of the privatisation process that makes the motivation
behind the choice of the "strategic sale" route suspect.
The remarkable feature of this method of privatisation is that management
control is handed over to a private investor in return for acquisition
of a minority stake. In the case of the airlines sector, by handing
over management control in return for purchases varying between 26
and 40 per cent of equity, the government is allowing one or a combination
of two or more minority private shareholders to transform the objectives
of the company. The implied willingness to trade social gains for
private profits could be traced to a desire to achieve either one
or a combination of two objectives. That of wanting to make the privatisation
offer unusually attractive, or that of wanting to use private management
as the hatchet with which to close "unprofitable" routes
and slash cross-subsidisation to improve profitability in return for
a share in those profits. That is, privatisation becomes a means of
cutting social expenditures, which are given a bad name by treating
them as "implicit subsidies" that in government parlance
has come to mean populist "give aways".
But even this is not easily achieved. The current performance of the
airlines sector is not merely the result of the adverse impact of
cross-subsidisation on financial profitability but of the beneficial
impact of offering a captive client to the operator in the form of
the many arms of government. Once social objectives are dropped and
competition and market principles made the rule, there is no logic
to the provision of such a captive market. If the government pursues
logic and allows full freedom to official travellers to choose their
airline on all routes, the expected gains from privatisation may remain
unrealised, especially since ownership change per se does not necessarily
improve profitability. If it does the value of the 50 per cent equity,
which the government has chosen to continue to hold in order to facilitate
privatisation, would collapse, making the whole exercise a financially
disastrous one.
It is not surprising therefore that the decision to privatise the
airline industry has been mired in controversy not just outside but
also within the government. According to reports, Civil Aviation Minister
Sharad Yadav has been a staunch opponent of the disinvestment move,
and it has taken some persuasion by Mr Jaitley and intervention by
the Prime Minister for the decision to go through the Cabinet Committee
on Disinvestment. This rather stubborn insistence on going ahead with
"strategic sales" in an area where there still remain strong
arguments for control by the state stems from many sources. Primarily
it comes from the ideological and political moorings of the BJP. First,
the BJP and the Jana Sangh out of which it evolved is the most economically
conservative and pro-business political formation in the country,
which has recently given up even the nationalist rhetoric that made
it appear as favouring domestic rather than international capital.
Second, in keeping with this transformation, the BJP under Prime Minister
Vajpayee has decided to virtually steal the "reform" agenda
from the Congress and make it its own, necessitating an acceleration
and intensification of the liberalisation process. Third, the BJP
has clearly decided to use this liberalisation process and the "modernity"
it is claimed to symbolise to divert attention from its deeply conservative,
retrogade and divisive social and cultural ideology.
These fundamental influences driving the BJP¹s reform agenda in general
and the privatisation plank in particular have been supported by more
immediate factors. One of these is the need to appease the G-7 in
general and the US in particular, by offering "big-ticket"
liberalisation as a sop for not overreacting to the BJP¹s "nuclear
natioinalism". The other is the need to deal with the contradiction
involved in placating domestic business with low tax rates, while
satisfying the demands from the IMF and the international financial
interests it represents, to rein in the fiscal deficit. The resources
garnered from privatisation help at least temporarily resolve this
conflict and provide the government with some additional resources
to go about its routine activities, even if at the expense of substantial
future revenues.
The fact that such a range of motives govern the process of privatisation
through strategic sale does, however, send out a damaging signal.
The desperation to sell potentially lucrative assets to the private
sector gives the "strategic buyer" a negotiating advantage.
A host of reasons can be found to undervalue assets and sell them
cheap. In the event, in the event of failure to ensure that the opposition
wins, reason prevails and indiscriminate privatisation halted, the
least that should be secured is transparency in the valuation process.
If not, a group of private investors are bound to take over the market
for airborne traffic at bargain prices, even though the process involves
considerable social cost.
|