|
|
|
|
India's
Growth Story Ends*
|
|
Jun
6th 2012, C.P. Chandrasekhar |
|
The
Indian summer of economic growth and resilience seems
at an end. The indicators are too many to ignore. GDP
growth is expected to be significantly lower than 7
per cent in financial year ending March 2012, down from
8.4 per cent in year ending March 2011. Manufacturing
expanded less than 3 per cent as compared with nearly
9 per cent in the previous year. The annual month-on-month
rate of inflation as measured by the national Consumer
Price Index had risen to 10.4 in April, from 9.4 per
cent in March, 8.8 per cent in February and 7.7 per
cent in January. Stagflation in the economy seems a
possibility.
Externally too there are signs of deterioration. The
trade deficit is estimated to have increased by 56 per
cent between 2010-11 and 2011-12 to touch 10.6 per cent
of GDP. Foreign exchange reserves are falling: by mid-May
foreign reserves had fallen by $2.6 billion relative
to end-March, $4.9 billion relative to end-December
and $15.7 billion relative to a year earlier. And the
RBI's reference rate for the rupee has depreciated by
more than 10 per cent over just 3 months. That is a
slew of bad news headlines.
To many this suggests that, as Europe sinks, India is
set to follow. So supporters of the UPA's economic dream
team are deserting the sinking ship. The government
attributes it to the global crisis, especially the European
one. But the downturn is not just the fallout of global
trends. In fact, till recently a resurgent India prided
itself on being "decoupled" from a global
economy that has been wallowing in crisis for close
to five years now. Not that India was completely unaffected
by that crisis. Rather 2008-09 was a difficult year
in many ways. Much lower growth, an exit of capital
and a depreciation of the currency gave cause for concern.
But that downturn was reversed rather quickly. A resilient
economy and a strong countercyclical stimulus from the
government, it was argued, countered the destabilisation
and restored growth.
The bravado implicit in the decoupling argument was
not without basis. For half a decade prior to 2008,
India had registered unusually high growth. Though the
infamous and low "Hindu rate of growth" was
transcended as far back as the 1980s, India's true growth
story began after 2003-04. It was as if a paradigm shift
had occurred. All of a sudden, a country attuned to
3 per cent rates of growth at first and 5-6 per cent
growth rates subsequently traversed to an 8-9 per cent
trajectory, with high savings and investment rates.
There were many blemishes: a laggard agriculture in
crisis, an industry that was diminishing in size and
employment intensity and deprivation that was stubbornly
high, to name a few. But who could grudge a remarkably
high rate of growth that made India the flavour of the
season for international investors and increased its
foreign reserves.
But this mixed performance did have implications. It
signalled the fact that there was a missing robustness
in the boom. That inadequacy came from many sources,
but principally from the fact that while the stimulus
to growth was largely domestic, those stimuli were tenuous.
The principal change in the external environment was
a surge in foreign capital flows to India (as also other
so-called emerging markets). The liquidity thus infused
into the system led to a boom in debt-financed investments
in housing and debt-financed purchases of automobiles
and durables. But private expansion was clearly driven
by measures of "liberalisation" that relaxed
constraints on the expansion of large capital. It also
engineered profit inflation through many means, including
the provision of cheap access to the private sector
to public assets and mineral and other resources. The
crisis did lead to a slowing down and even reversal
of capital flows. But simultaneously signs of excess
credit accumulation and allegations of corrupt practices
favouring sections of capital have dampened the other
stimuli as well. It is the weakening of these stimuli
that has brought the growth story to an early end.
It is not just that the recovery from the crisis has
not been sustained enough. Despite individual years
of good monsoon-led growth in agriculture (as in the
last year), overall growth is slowing significantly
because industry is slowing and services are losing
dynamism. Even as growth slows, inflation, which had
emerged as the country's principal challenge, is showing
no signs of going away. Inflation had initially moderated
a bit as compared to the peak levels it had reached
last year and the year before; but it is now again bound
upwards. With the government committed to raising the
prices of oil in line with the spurt in international
prices, this problem will only worsen. Lower growth
and higher inflation seem to be the prospect in the
medium-term future.
It is at this time that two other developments have
‘pooped' the party. The first is a widening of the deficit
in exports relative to imports. Exports are slowing
because of the persisting global crisis, though over
financial year 2011-12 as a whole, exports rose 21 per
cent in dollar terms to $303.7 billion as against the
previous year's $251.1 billion. But the trend is one
of slowdown. In the month of March 2012, exports were
six per cent lower at $28.6 billion, compared with $30.4
billion in March 2011. But the deficit is substantial
due to a rise in imports, because oil prices are exploding
for geopolitical reasons and Indians are rushing into
imported gold as a safe investment. But even for the
whole financial year, imports grew at a much faster
32.15 per cent to $488.6 billion. Oil imports were up
47 per cent (at $155.63 billion) relative to the previous
year's $105.9 billion. Non-oil imports also grew 26
per cent to $333 billion ($263.8 billion). And in this
case the trend is one of further increase. Imports during
March grew 24 per cent to $42.5 billion ($34.2 billion),
with oil imports rising 32.45 per cent to $15.83 billion
and non-oil imports by 20 per cent to $26.7 billion.
Over the year, the trade deficit or the gap between
exports and imports during 2011-12 grew to $185 billion
in 2011-12, which swallowed a large share of India's
revenues from remittances and services exports. The
current account deficit seems to be widening in recent
months. A consequence has been a weaker rupee that has
been sliding gradually from the troublesome highs it
touched in the not too distant past.
As the trade and current account deficits in India's
external payments widen and the rupee weakens, a second
disconcerting external development is under way. Foreign
investors who were rushing into India are holding back
and even exiting. According to the SEBI, FIIs who were
pumping in huge volumes of dollars into the debt and
equity market, reduced their net investment to $387
million in March, took out $923 million in April and
had brought in only $249 million in May till the 21st.
Initially this was because they were selling out in
India to garner surpluses that could cover losses or
meet commitments at home. But, now, it is because they
too are wary of the India prospect and fear a further
devaluation of the rupee. The result is a decline in
reserves and expectations of a further depreciation.
Enter the speculators, who are making sure that the
rupee slumps by betting that it will.
Rupee deprecation in other times may have helped by
improving the competitiveness of India's exports by
making them cheaper. But that is little help in an environment
when a sluggish world economy is demanding less goods
and services overall. What rupee depreciation does in
the current environment is increase the domestic prices
of India's imports including that of oil, aggravating
inflation. It also squeezes firms that, encouraged by
much lower interest rates abroad and the liberalised
rules on borrowing, accumulated large foreign debt to
finance local expenditures. That was a boon when the
rupee was strong. But now, the dollar payments due on
those debts are draining far more rupees, affecting
corporate bottom lines adversely. That too depresses
investment and growth, and threatens to trigger a downward
spiral flagged now by a collapsing rupee. A collapsing
currency is a sure negative signal for international
investors. India has been downgraded and so have Indian
banks been. The downward spiral needs to be pre-empted.
However, there appears to be no convincing response
from the government thus far. The RBI is wary about
stoking inflation by reducing rates to spur growth.
Given the deficit on the government's budget and India's
relatively high public debt to GDP the government is
wary of increasing its spending to counter the crisis,
partly because it fears that larger fiscal deficits
or higher taxation would upset foreign investors and
hasten their exit.
In the event, we have the Finance Minister speaking
of the need for austerity and harsh decisions amidst
a slowdown in growth. That would only convert falling
growth into a recession. Further, the "harsh decisions"
involve measures such as cutting subsidies to reduce
expenditure and raising oil prices. Combined with the
increase in the prices of imports as a result of the
rupee's depreciation, these administered price hikes
would only fuel inflation, and further aggravate the
tendency towards stagflation.
The potential for a cumulative slide has already triggered
a bandwagon effect. As noted, rating agencies are downgrading
India and international investors, heeding these agencies,
seem to be reducing their exposure. Shaken by this response,
the government seems set to implement austerity. That
could worsen the downturn without correcting either
inflation or the balance of payments. But the government
is opting for these measures because of the legacy of
financial liberalisation in the form of the accumulated
presence of foreign finance in the country. All policy
is being viewed first in terms of the effect it would
have on the confidence of those investors, rather than
its efficacy in addressing the problems at hand.
It is here that the similarity with the European predicament
is apparent. There too, the accumulation of large volumes
of public debt has made sovereign default a possibility
if additional credit to meet expenditures was not forthcoming.
However, additional credit to "help" countries
avoid default was provided only on the condition that
they opted for austerity. This imposed huge burdens
on the people in the form of increased unemployment,
reduced incomes and a collapse of social security outlays.
Cutbacks in government expenditure were expected to
reduce deficits and release the wherewithal to finance
future debt service commitments. The outcome was contrary
to expectations. Rather than reduce deficits and generate
surpluses, the output contraction resulting from expenditure
cuts reduced revenues, making it impossible for these
countries to meet their deficit reduction targets. A
cycle of enhanced austerity, lower growth and worsening
debt service capacity followed, with no solution in
sight. It is clear from this that in bad times countries
need to get out of the slowdown-austerity-recession
cycle by substantially increasing expenditures to restore
growth and employment. This would, over time, also raise
the revenues to finance some of their debt commitments.
Though there are important differences between India
and Europe, there are two similarities here that need
to be recognised. The first is that India's fiscal deficit
and debt to GDP ratios have also been declared to be
unacceptably high by international finance, which has
a large and influential presence in the country. The
second is that this large presence of international
investors and creditors, not only increases economic
instability, but also induces an element of "policy
paralysis" because of a reduction in the state's
room for manoeuvre. Central to that paralysis is a self-imposed
limit on spending resulting from a fear of raising resources
through taxation and financing expenditures with borrowing.
Even when confronted with slowing growth, the government
tends to adopt austerity measures that trap the country
in a recession. This has already occurred in Europe.
It is a real possibility for India.
The way out, as clarified by economists with divergent
inclinations, is to escape from this vicious cycle by
expanding spending, and finding ways other than expenditure
contraction to address inflation or balance of payments
difficulties. But that requires not only ignoring the
demands of finance, but also countering its speculative
manoeuvres. In contexts like India, controls on the
movement of footloose and speculative capital are a
must to give the government the required room for manoeuvre.
But that does not seem to be the route the government
is adopting. So the downturn, as in Europe, may soon
turn into a full-fledged crisis.
* This
article was originally published in the Frontline, Volume
29-Issue 11: June 02-15, 2012, and is available at
http://www.frontlineonnet.com/fl2911/stories/2012
0615291100400.htm
|
|
|
|
|
|
|