But this rise in the fiscal deficit is not merely
the result of past non-interest expenditures financed through debt,
which have contributed to an increase in outlays on interest payments.
It is also the result of the change in the manner in which government
deficits have been financed in recent times as a result of financial
reform. Until the early 1990s, a considerable part of the deficit on
the government's budget was financed with borrowing from the central
bank against ad hoc Treasury Bills issued by the government. The interest
rate on such borrowing was, at around 4.6 per cent, much lower than
the interest rate on borrowing from the open market. A crucial aspect
of financial reform has been the reduction of such borrowing from the
central bank to zero, resulting in a sharp rise in the average interest
rate on government borrowing.
The shift away from borrowing from the central
bank has been advocated on three grounds. First, that such borrowing
(deficit financing) is inflationary. Second, that it undermines the
role of monetary policy by depriving the central bank of any autonomy.
And, third, that it undermines much needed fiscal discipline by providing
the government with ready access to credit at a low rate of interest.
We need to consider each of these in some detail. The notion that the
budget deficit, defined in India as that part of the deficit which is
financed by borrowing from the central bank, is more inflationary than
a fiscal deficit financed with open market borrowing, stems from the
idea that the latter amounts to a draft on the savings of the private
sector, while the former merely creates more money.
In the current context where new government
securities are ineligible for refinance from the Reserve Bank of India
(RBI), this is partly true. This is in part because the need for refinance
to create additional credit arises only when the banking system is stretched
to the limits of its credit-creating capacity. If, on the other hand,
as is true today, banks are flush with liquidity, government borrowing
from the open market adds to the credit created by the system rather
than displacing or crowding out the private sector from the market for
credit. This too can be inflationary if supply-side bottlenecks exist.
But even if government borrowing is not financed through a draft on
private savings but through the printing of money, such borrowing is
inflationary only if the system is at full employment or is characterised
by supply bottlenecks in certain sectors.
As mentioned earlier, not only is the industrial
sector burdened with excess capacity at present, but the government
is burdened with excess foodstocks and foreign exchange reserves. This
implies that there are no supply constraints to prevent "excess" spending
from triggering output as opposed to price increases. Since inflation
is already at an all-time low, this provides a strong basis for an expansionary
fiscal stance, financed if necessary with borrowing from the central
bank. To summarise, in the current context a monetised deficit is not
only non-inflationa ry, but virtuous from the point of view of growth.
This brings us to the second objection to a
monetised deficit, namely, that it undermines the autonomy of the central
bank. This demand for autonomy, which is a central component of International
Monetary Fund (IMF)-style financial reform, assumes that once relieved
of the task of financing the government's deficit, the RBI would be
in a far better position to control money supply and therefore "free"
to use monetary policy as a device to control inflation, manage balance
of payments, and influence growth. In practice, IMF-style financial
reform has hardly enhanced the autonomy of the central bank, since it
not merely involves curbing the Government's borrowing from the RBI,
but also liberalising regulation of capital flows into and out of the
country. Since such flows are extremely volatile, the central bank is
constantly forced to adjust to these "autonomous" capital movements.
In recent times, for example, portfolio inflows which went way above
the $50 million a day mark increased foreign exchange availability in
the market and threatened to raise the value of the rupee, even when
the trade deficit was widening.
This has required the central bank to intervene
in the foreign exchange market and purchase dollars in order to stabilise
the rupee, resulting in a sharp increase in the foreign exchange reserves
with the RBI. Since an increase in the central bank's foreign assets
has as its corollary an increase in its liabilities in the form of the
supply of money, monetary policy remains solely concerned with neutralising
the effects of foreign capital inflows. Relieved of the dominance of
fiscal over monetary policy, the RBI now finds itself straitjacketed
by international finance.
Finally, the evidence cited earlier makes it
clear that even putting an end to the practice of monetising the deficit
has hardly had any effect on the fiscal situation. Fiscal deficits remain
high, although they are now financed by high-interest, open-ma rket
borrowing. The only result is that the interest burden of the government
tends to shoot up, reducing its manoeuvrability with regard to capital
and non-interest current expenditures. This effect of financial reform
on the fiscal manoeuvrability of t he state can be assessed by comparing
actual fiscal trends with a hypothetical situation where the government
had continued financing the same share of its deficit (around 30 per
cent) with central bank borrowing as it did in 1989-90. In that case,
a simple simulation exercise reveals, the interest burden in the Budget
would have risen from Rs.17,757 crores to only Rs.88,464 crores in 2000-2001
as compared with the estimate of Rs. 101,266 crores recorded in this
year's Budget papers. Such a possibility of saving in interest payments
of close to Rs.13,000 crores or 12.6 per cent in the terminal year is
obviously the culmination of a rising gap between actual and hypothetical
interest payments starting from the mid-1990s when the practice of monetising
a part of the deficit was done away with. This cumulative saving would
have implied a huge reduction in the size of the fiscal deficit, assuming
that expenditures remained the same. Over the 1990s as a whole, the
cumulative reduction in the deficit would have been more than Rs.100,000
crores, which is far more than what the government could possibly have
mobilised through disinvestment.