On
February 4, the Reserve Bank of India took a major step
forward towards full convertibility of the rupee. It
announced that resident Indians can, with immediate
effect, remit an amount of up to $25,000 per calendar
year for any current or capital account transaction, or
a combination of both. This implies that resident
Indians would not just be able to open and operate
foreign currency accounts outside India, but can use the
money remitted to those accounts to acquire financial or
immovable assets without prior approval from the RBI.
On the surface, the sum of $25,000 involved may appear small, especially
when compared to net capital inflows into the country of $12 billion in
2002-03 and $6 billion in the first quarter (April-June) of 2003-04, and
reserve accumulation of $17 billion during 2002-03, and around 25 billion
during April to December 2003. But, looked at otherwise, if one million
Indians, or just 0.1 per cent of the country's population choose to avail
of the facility in full, the outflow would be adequate to wipe out the
foreign exchange reserves accumulated during the first three quarters
of a year (2003-04) that has seen record inflows of capital. It is not
India's new and old rich alone who would seek to exploit the new ‘facility'.
The large numbers of middle class households who have members moving abroad
on H1 B visas or for educational purposes would see some reason for holding
an account, if not making some investment, abroad. A million may not be
a large figure for the number willing every year to transfer the equivalent
of Rs. 11.5 lakh abroad at current exchange rates. Not surprisingly, within
a day after the new facility was announced, banks have rushed to press,
to advertise their willingness to manage remittances under this head for
interested clients.
Needless to say, if all or a large part of capital
inflows are consumed in this fashion, it could send out
a signal that the country is losing its ability to meet
its repatriation commitments, either in the form of the
returns that would accrue to foreign investors or in the
form of permission to exit from investments in the
country. This could slow capital inflows or even result
in outflows, leading to a collapse in reserves and a
financial crisis. This is typically the way in which
countries that are temporarily the favourites of foreign
investors and experience a capital inflow surge often
find themselves the victims of outflows that lead to
crisis. The "feast-or-famine" syndrome characteristic of
capital flows to emerging markets has been documented
widely. A reading of that literature does warrant the
conclusion that by beginning the journey to full
convertibility, the government has opened the sluice
gates to outflows that can empty its foreign exchange
reserves.
An analysis of the sources of reserve accumulation by
the RBI over a long period points to the important role
of inflows in the form of NRI deposits and foreign
institutional investor investments. Outstanding NRI
deposits increased from US$ 13.7 billion at end-March
1991 to US$ 31.3 billion at end-September 2003.
Cumulative net FII investments, increased from US$ 827
million at end-December 1993 to US$ 19.2 billion at
end-September 2003. These kinds of investments rarely,
if ever at all, finance new investments in the domestic
economy. These are also typically inflows that would be
reversed in case of any sign of uncertainty.
Thus, comparisons of likely outflows with the size of
inflows and the extent of reserve accumulation are not
without some basis. Reserve accumulation occurs when the
RBI is forced to intervene in the foreign currency
market and purchase dollars or other foreign currencies.
This it is forced to do when large capital inflows
result in a surplus of foreign exchange in the system,
since the supply of foreign exchange exceeds demand from
firms and individuals for permitted current and capital
account transactions such as imports, private or
business travel, remittance for gifts, donations, study
abroad, medical treatment, investment abroad and so on.
When the supply of foreign exchange exceeds such demand,
the rupee tends to appreciate vis-ŕ-vis foreign
currencies under India's liberalized and market-driven
exchange rate regime. A rising rupee increases the
dollar value of India's exportables and adversely
affects her export competitiveness. It is to prevent
such appreciation that the RBI has been purchasing
foreign exchange in the market and enhancing its
reserves.
Beyond a point, however, increasing reserves are a
problem for the central bank. When the foreign exchange
assets of the RBI rise, so do its liabilities, which
typically imply an increase in money supply. Since
allowing that to happen amounts to loosing control of
its monetary policy lever, the central bank chooses to
retrench other assets such as government securities to
sterilize inflows.
Unfortunately for the Reserve Bank of India, foreign
capital inflows have in recent months been massive and
unrelenting. The consequent huge and rapid increase in
its reserves, can no more be sterilized easily, since
the central bank has already brought down its holding of
government securities substantially.
Excessive reserve accumulation is a problem also because
of its negative balance of payments implications.
Investors bringing in the capital earn minimum returns
of around 7 percent. The maximum would be many multiples
of that, especially from capital gains associated with
recent investments in the stock market. These returns
have to be paid out in foreign exchange. On the other
hand, when the dollar flowing into the country are
acquired by the RBI and invested through central and
commercial banks, the returns are much lower. According
to the RBI, during the year 2002-03 (July-June), the
return on foreign currency assets, excluding capital
gains less depreciation, decreased to 2.8 per cent from
4.1 per cent during 2001-02, because of lower
international interest rates. This implies that the
interest associated with capital inflow and its
accretion as reserves involves little foreign exchange
earning but substantial foreign exchange payouts.
Finally, it is becoming diplomatically increasingly
difficult to accumulate reserves in order to prevent
currency appreciation. India has been identified along
with China as a country whose large reserves prove that
it has an "undervalued" currency that discriminates
against imports from the US. The pressure to allow the
currency to appreciate is therefore on the increase.
For all these reasons, it had become clear to the
central bank and the government that something had to be
done to prevent further rapid reserve accumulation. The
choice, therefore, was either to curb flows or to
stimulate the demand for foreign exchange. Given its
unthinking commitment to liberalization and "reform",
it's the latter route that the government has chosen.
Recent months have, therefore, seen not just irrational
and sometimes bizarre trade liberalisation manoeuvres,
such as across-the-board duty reductions and the license
to bring in laptops duty free as part of baggage, but
the relaxation of ceilings on remittances abroad for
purposes as varied as education, health and investment.
All of these have proved inadequate given the fact that
India has proved to be the flavour of the season for
foreign investors, who have rushed into the country in
herd-like fashion.
It is this set of circumstances, rather than rational
decision-making, that has forced the government to all
on a sudden liberalize controls on capital account
outflows. The sequence has to be noted. First,
regulations regarding purely financial inflows are
liberalized to attract capital into the country so as to
finance the outflows that trade liberalization was
expected to result in. Since the initial response of
foreign investors was lukewarm, further liberalization,
in the form of relaxing ceilings on FII holdings of
equity in firms in different sectors, was resorted to.
Suddenly, for reasons extraneous to the performance of
the Indian economy, which has grown at an indifferent
rate for at least three consecutive years before the
current "recovery", inflows accelerate. Unable to manage
those inflows, the government attempts to encourage
foreign exchange profligacy through liberalization of
foreign exchange access for various current account
transactions. When even that proves inadequate, it opts
for capital account convertibility.
The problem is that when
controls on capital account outflows are liberalized, it
is difficult to control the volume of outflows. And if
large outflows raise the threat of depreciation in the
value of the rupee, outflows accelerate and capital
flight out of rupee denominated assets would occur.
Having whetted the appetite of India's rich for a
financial foothold abroad, it would be extremely
difficult to reverse the decision. Moreover, any such
reversal would encourage the flight of financial
investors out of the country. A currency and financial
collapse would be inevitable. In short, the sluice gates
have been opened. It is, therefore, clearly time to
prepare for the coming crisis.
|