By
now it is commonplace to bemoan the poor state of health services
in India. Public provision of health services is very inadequately
funded and its facilities are plagued by overcrowding, shortage of
essential items and of skilled personnel, and insufficient accountability
to citizens. Private involvement in health provision is beset by rising
costs and problems of exclusion, huge and growing differentials in
the services available to rich and poor, and inadequate supervision
associated with various manifestations of moral hazard. As a result,
India’s health indicators are among the worst in the world, explaining
to a large extent our appalling low position in the international
Human Development Index.
All this is so well known that it scarcely evokes much reaction anymore
beyond a defeated shrug of the shoulders, even among normally concerned
citizens. What is more surprising is the apparent paucity of ideas
on how to deal with the current mess, beyond the very obvious need
to increase public spending on health. That is what makes the recently
released Report of the Independent Commission on Development and Health
in India (''Governance of the Health Sector in India: Has the state
abdicated its role?'', Voluntary Health Association of India, New
Delhi: 2008) such an important contribution.
The Report, authored by former Union Health Secretary Javid Chowdhury
and other Commission members, makes a number of important points and
suggestions. Several of these are worth reiterating here.
The first point that is generally recognised but still deserves to
be highlighted, is the sheer extent of the regional imbalances in
both process and outcome indicators for health. The average health
status for the country as a whole is poor and per capita spending
on health is also very low by international standards. Public health
spending is indeed among the lowest in the world, both as share of
GDP and per capita. But this disguises very sharp differences across
states. At one end is a group of states (Kerala, Maharashtra, Himachal
Pradesh and Tamil Nadu) accounting for 18.8 per cent of the population,
with health indicators similar to those in more developed middle-income
countries like Venezuela, Argentina and Saudi Arabia. At the other
end of the spectrum are the Bimaru-plus states (Uttar Pradesh, Orissa,
Madhya Pradesh, Assam, Rajasthan, Bihar and Jharkhand), comprising
nearly 42 per cent of the population, for whom the indicators are
close to sub-Saharan and other low-income countries like Sudan, Nigeria
and Myanmar.
The differences across states do not simply relate to the health outcomes,
but also extend to the financing of health expenditure and the implications
for the people. Thus, the poorer states also had less public provision:
in 2001-02, public health spending as a percentage of total health
expenditure ranged from 7.5 per cent (or Rs 84 per capita) in Uttar
Pradesh to 89.2 per cent (Rs 836 per capita) in Mizoram. However,
not a single major state achieved the basic threshold level of Rs
500 per capita public health spending.
The regional disparities also extend to the availability of medical
personnel. The availability of graduate allopathic doctors in the
country as a whole is only 0.6 per thousand population, but they are
unevenly spread, much more concentrated in the South and in more developed
states (so that Punjab has more than five times the availability of
Uttar Pradesh). Also, these doctors tend to converge on urban and
per-urban areas, leaving rural and backward areas especially deprived.
Even medical colleges are unevenly spread: the four southern states
have 63 per cent of the colleges and 67 per cent of the seats. The
states with the biggest shortfalls in medical personnel are predictably
the Bimaru states (in this case Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan,
Uttar Pradesh, Jharkhand and Chattisgarh) along with the Northeastern
states, Orissa and Haryana. The regulation and monitoring of personnel
also leave much to be desired: the statutory councils for doctors,
nurses, dentists and others are almost dysfunctional.
So people are forced to turn to private health services, and in the
poorer states more poor people are forced to pay because government
provision is unavailable or inadequate. Thus, in the poorest states,
illnesses involving hospitalisation are more prone to break poor families’
finances. The Report quotes the NSSO Survey to show that in Bihar
and Uttar Pradesh, more than one third of those who were hospitalised
fell into poverty on account of medical expenditure.
Not only are private, or out-of-pocket, medical expenses borne by
households far too high in India, but there is also evidence to indicate
that they have gone up sharply in recent times. According to the NSSO,
urban hospitalisation costs increased by 126 per cent between 1995-96
and 2003-04, while rural hospitalisation costs increased by 78 per
cent. It is alarming to note that private costs were often borne by
households that simply could not afford them. In general, the Commission
notes that the one-fifth of the population that is just above the
poverty line would automatically slip into poverty if they faced even
one serious health crisis.
One important item of medical expenditure for which the increase in
costs has been particularly rapid is therapeutic drugs. The average
drug expenditure met out-of-pocket is 75 per cent, but once again
those residing in the poorer states are the worst off even in this
respect. The share of drugs in medical expenditure of households (both
in-patient and out-patient) was as high as 90 per cent in Orissa and
nearly that in Rajasthan, Bihar, Himachal Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh.
In no state was the ratio less than 61 per cent, indicating clearly
that the health system is ''over-medicalised''.
This growing expenditure on drugs reflects not only the impact of
the new patent regime, but also the lack of adequate regulation of
the Indian drug manufacturing sector and a lax drug policy that allows
the proliferation of non-essential and even irrational or hazardous
drugs.
A crucial area that has recently come into the news is the absence
of public health security, even in terms of the provision of basic
vaccines and drugs. Lack of investment in public facilities has meant
that in general they cannot meet the WHO’s standards, and the policy
of relying on the private manufacturers to fill the gap has proved
to be futile as they simply did not deliver. As a result, there is
now a shortage of basic vaccines and other essential drugs, which
is holding up crucial immunisation programmes and threatens a current
and future public health crisis in several states. As for personal
health, government health services are obviously inadequate, and the
private health insurance schemes that are in existence cover very
small pools of people and do not ensure risk-sharing.
So we have a system that is underfunded, under-regulated, very expensive
for the people given levels of income, irrational and hugely inefficient.
What is to be done about all this? The Independent Commission on Development
and Health in India makes several very important recommendations,
covering not only more public expenditure but also its allocation,
more and different types of regulation, new approaches to training
and initiatives to change the current tendencies to over-medicalisation
and excessive dependence upon curative rather than preventive health
care.
The suggestions are eminently sensible. It is foolish to argue that
overall lack of resources in a poor country is the fundamental constraint.
The examples of our neighbours, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, show that
much can be achieved in this regard even in the context of a relatively
low income developing country. Indeed, it is sad to think that we
still even need to argue in favour of these very obvious and urgent
requirements.