Diversification of production structures and exports has traditionally
been seen as the key to fast development. Indeed, this has been taken so
much for granted, that for much of the past half century the debate among
economists has been not so much about the desirability of this goal, but
of the policies required to achieve it. Marketist neoliberal economists
have argued that the best way is through liberalisation, deregulation and
greater integration of domestic markets with world markets, while
structuralist economists have emphasised the need for domestic structural
change assisted by trade restrictions which promote industrialisation.
In either case, the need to
enter new forms of production, to diversify away from traditional exports,
and ideally to enter high-value manufacturing production, has been taken
for granted. But some new research (discussed in the latest Trade and
Development Report produced by UNCTAD) suggests that even this may not
be as unproblematic as it appears, and that product diversification in
itself ensures neither more dynamic exports not even higher incomes from
such activities.
On the face of it, developing countries as a group have achieved an
impressive degree of production diversification over the past two decades,
and this has also been reflected in export performance. From the early
1980s, merchandise exports from developing countries having been growing
much faster (at 11.3 per cent per annum) than the world average of 8.4 per
cent.
More
significantly, there has been a bug shift in developing country exports,
away from primary commodities (whose share has fallen from 51 per cent in
1980 to only 19 per cent in 1998) and towards manufactured goods, which
now account for more than 80 per cent of their exports. What seems most
promising is that the largest increase has been in the increased exports
of manufactures with high skill and technology intensity, whose share
jumped from 12 per cent of total developing country exports in 1980 to 31
per cent in 1998.
Despite all these apparently
positive signs, however, there is no evidence of improved income shares
for developing country exporters. In fact, the Trade and Development
Report 2002 argues that “while the share of developing countries in
world manufacturing exports, including those of rapidly growing high-tech
products, has been expanding rapidly, the income earned from such
activities does not appear to share in this dynamism.
This becomes apparent from a comparison of shares in exports and value
added in world manufacturing. While developing countries as a group more
than doubled their share of world manufacturing exports from 10.6 per cent
in 1980 to 26.5 per cent in 1998, their share of manufacturing value added
increased by less than half, from 16.6 per cent to 23.8 per cent. By
contrast, developed countries experienced a substantial decline in share
of world manufacturing exports, from 82.3 per cent to 70.9 per cent. But
at the same time their share of world manufacturing value added actually
increased, from 64.5 per cent to 73.3 per cent.
This means that developed countries moved up the value chain much faster,
and that developing country exporters have continued to face problems in
translating export volume growth into income growth. The problem is
compounded by the fact that developing countries remain net importers of
manufactured goods, indeed they have become more so. Imports of
manufactured goods have continuously outpaced exports of such goods for
developing countries, unlike developed countries. Meanwhile, manufacturing
exports have consistently exceeded the value of manufacturing value added,
once again the opposite of developed countries.
How can we square
this with the evidence on product diversification and entry into dynamic
exporting sectors that was mentioned above ? After all, developing
countries have been increasingly active traders in what are seen as the
most dynamic sectors of the world economy : computers and office
equipment; telecommunications, audio and video equipment; semiconductors.
But the point is that
international production and trade in these sectors exhibit a relatively
new pattern, whereby there is a “vertical disintegration of production”
across locations. That is, different parts of a production process are
dispersed across different geographical locations, and goods travel across
several such locations over the entire process before reaching final
consumers. This is also true of the other major dynamic export sector :
textiles and clothing.
In such
sectors, the total value of recorded trade far exceeds the value added.
But by and large most developing countries are confined to the
labour-intensive processes in this overall production. This means it is
misleading to look simply at the “high-tech” nature of the final product.
Many of these processes involve essentially low-skilled assembly-type
operations, in which developing country locations compete with each other
by virtue of their cheap labour rather than any other criterion. This also
means that much of the value-added that does accrue in this process is
garnered by the multinational corporations that are organising the
production in this way, rather than by the economies which are hosting
them.
But there are other factors,
apart from this firm-based separation and geographical relocation of
production, which may have played a role in reducing returns to developing
country exporters. The most important of these is the well-known fallacy
of composition : the idea that what may be possible and attractive for an
individual exporting country, may turn out to have much reduced or even
opposite effects when many countries try to follow the same path.
This problem has been well established for a range of primary products for
some time now, but recent evidence suggests that it is also becoming
increasingly significant in world trade in manufactured goods. Thus, the
slowdown in exports from the East/Southeast Asian region from 1996, which
preceded the financial crisis, has been attributed to the same fallacy of
composition. (Ghosh and Chandrasekhar, Crisis as Conquest : Learning from
East Asia, Orient Longman 2001) As more and more countries in the region
entered the world market for office equipment and semiconductor related
items, overproduction meant that prices crashed. Only the People’s
Republic of China and the Philippines showed very high rates of growth ox
exports in this category in that year : for all other countries in the
region, exports in this sector stagnated or declined.
The electronics sector typifies the problem of overproducing standardised
mass products with high import content, which have experienced bother
higher volatility and steeper falls since 1995. But the same is true of a
range of manufactured goods exports from developing countries, which is
why there is evidence of a general terms of trade movement against
manufactures of the South.
Since more and more developing countries are turning to precisely this
strategy, and basing their hopes on relocative FDI to achieve it, those
already within the loop become vulnerable as well. Thus the pattern of
high export volume growth and relatively slow or stagnant income growth
has become marked even for middle income “super traders: such as Hong Kong
and Mexico.
In addition, developing countries increasingly try to offer fiscal and
trade-related concessions to would-be exporters, especially relocative
MNCs. When this is combined with other conditions currently prevailing in
the world economy, such as the increasingly crowded markets for
labour-intensive goods, weak aggregate demand growth and protectionist
tendencies in the advanced countries, it is not surprising that increase
export volumes in these sectors have not translated into higher real
revenues.
Ironically, it turns out that some primary products actually performed
better in world trade markets than many of these manufactured goods. The
most “market-dynamic” agricultural commodities have outperformed most
manufactured goods in terms of export volumes and values. These include
silk, beverages, cereal preparation, preserved food, sugar preparations,
manufactured tobacco, chocolate, fish and seafood. However, apart from
silk (in which China has a 70 per cent market share), these other
commodities are dominated by developed country producers. Other primary
commodities which are major exports of most developing countries, have
continued to languish.
The lesson from all this
should not be simply be to despair that nothing seems to work in terms of
export focus for developing countries. Rather, this year’s TDR serves as
an important reminder that the current pattern of export-orientation,
based either on traditional primary production or relocative FDI-based
exports relying on labour-intensive parts of wider manufacturing
processes, may not deliver sustained benefits in terms of income growth.
The earlier more successful East Asian strategy was based on targeted
trade and industrial policies rather than on market-determined processes.
While such strategic trade policies may have become much more difficult in
the current context, what this Report suggests is that some alternative
strategy must be found if developing countries are to negotiate their
integration into the world economy in a way that actually furthers their
development prospects.
|