Symbolism
is a crucial adjunct of central banking. Huge buildings of solid stone,
high ceilings, steel vaults and managers in suits are the images that
come to mind when one thinks of the institution that is presumed to have
final financial authority and serves as the lender of last resort. Firmness,
sobriety, integrity and a role as the keeper of the national interest
are the attributes that are sought to be symbolised. More recently, this
image of the central bank has sought to be strengthened by the unsubstantiated
claim that financial reform has increased the independence of the central
bank and its governor.
Not surprisingly, in recent years, the routine and periodic reviews and
policy statements of the Reserve Bank of India have taken on a ritualistic
flavour, almost matching the attention directed at the annual budget of
the Ministry of Finance. What is more, the assessments of the country's
economic health emanating from the central bank are seen as more sober,
reliable and technically sound than those issued by the Finance Ministry,
which is rightly seen as having a penchant for talking up the economy.
Yet, judging by its Annual Policy Statement for 2005-06 issued late April,
in practice the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) appears to be doing little
by way of macroeconomic management. With nominal interest rates soft,
inflation in the five per cent range, GDP growth reasonable and liquidity
easy, there is little to be done, many would argue. Hence, in the view
of many observers the statement was “along expected lines.” Having estimated
GDP growth at 7 per cent in 2005-06 and inflation on a point-to-point
at a reasonable 5.0-5.5 per cent, the RBI has chosen to leave the cash
reserve ratio (CRR) and the Bank Rate untouched. It has only raised by
0.25 per cent the reverse repo rate or the return that commercial banks
earn on funds deposited with the RBI in lieu of government securities
provided by the latter. This marginal change is not seen as reflecting
a pro-active monetary stance.
Assessments of the minor shift in policy for the coming season have focused
on its likely implications for liquidity in the system, since the measure
may soak up excess cash in circulation. They also focus on the likely
impact of the reverse repo rate hike on the interest rate on government
securities and on the structure of interest rates in general. By mopping
up loose cash and making credit more expensive, the reverse repo rate
hike is seen as having an impact on economic activity that would be enough
to limit the effects of the inflationary expectations generated by the
high level of oil prices. Thus while ensuring that money supply requirements
resulting from reasonable growth are met, by leaving the CRR untouched,
the central bank is seen to have exercised some caution with regard to
the inflation that could be triggered by higher international commodity
prices.
The difficulty with this conventional reading of the situation is that
it makes the central bank a marginal player in macro management. After
all, the threat of inflation is currently external and primarily on account
of adjustment of domestic oil prices to international levels. Inflation
in the prices of commodities other than mineral oils as measured on a
point-to-point basis by the Wholesale Price Index, worked out to just
3.5 per cent in 2004-05, as against 4.7 per cent in the previous year.
So, measures to dampen movements in the prices of those commodities can
hardly be expected to compensate for the inflation that can be triggered
by external developments such as sharp increases in oil or steel prices.
In sum, the central bank seems to have once again done virtually nothing.
However, on occasion, the central bank has shown signs of turning pro-active,
as for example when Governor Reddy announced that it was time to control
the surge in capital inflows into the country. If he could not convert
his perception into practice it was because he was pressurised to hold
back and even withdraw his almost innocuous plea at a late night press
briefing. Could it be that the image of passivity arises because the central
bank, whose hands have been tied by the government, is caught up with
the principal challenge it confronts today: that of managing the rupee
in the face of the surge in capital flows into the economy?
The surge in capital flows clearly persisted through financial year 2004-05.
During April-December 2004, net capital inflows amounted to a massive
$20.7 billion. Much of this was in the form of portfolio investment ($5.1
billion), external commercial borrowings ($4.1 billion), short-term credit
($2.7 billion), and other capital ($4.3 billion). Foreign direct investment
amounted to just $2.2 billion and NRI deposits registered net outflows
to the tune of $1.3 billion.
Fortunately for the RBI, a part of these flows were expended directly
by the system, as reflected in the deficit in the current account of the
balance of payments (BoP). The current account of India's BoP had recorded
a surplus for the three years ending 2003-04, implying that India did
not need any capital inflow to finance its current transactions. Exports
and invisible receipts, especially in the form of remittances and revenues
from software and IT-enabled services exports, were more that enough to
cover the country's foreign exchange demands. However, during April-December
2004, the current account showed a deficit of $7.4 billion as against
a surplus of US$4.8 billion in the corresponding period of the previous
year.
This was partly the result of a widening of the trade deficit, principally
because of increased outflows on account of oil imports. During April-February
2004-05, oil imports rose by 44 per cent, as compared with 15.7 per cent
in the previous year, while non-oil imports registered a 33.3 per cent
increase as compared with 28.8 per cent. With exports in dollar terms
growing at 27.1 per cent (as compared with 16.4 per cent), the trade deficit
widened to US $ 23.8 billion as compared with US $ 13.7 billion in the
previous year.
However, despite the rising trade deficit, invisible receipts from software
services ($12.2 billion during April-December) and private transfers ($15.5
billion) kept the current account deficit well below the volume of capital
flows during this period. Thus the deficit on the current account of the
BoP notwithstanding India was awash with surplus foreign exchange. To
prevent the resulting excess supply of foreign exchange from ensuring
an appreciation of the rupee, that would affect the competitiveness of
India's exports, the RBI had to step in and purchase foreign currencies.
As a result, the net accretion to foreign exchange reserves, including
valuation changes, amounted to $18.2 billion during April-December 2004.
With the RBI's foreign assets rising, managing the impact of that increase
on domestic liquidity has proved a major problem. Increases in reserve
money, provide the basis for a substantial increase in liquidity in the
system. Interestingly, however, The increase in reserve money during 2004-05
at 12.1 per cent (Rs.52,616 crore) was lower than the increase of 18.3
per cent (Rs.67,451 crore) in the previous year. Part of the reason was
the neutralising effect that a rising current account deficit had on capital
inflows. RBI's foreign currency assets (adjusted for revaluation) increased
by Rs.1,15,044 crore as compared with an increase of Rs.1,41,428 crore
in the previous year.
Further, the government has found new ways of “sterilising” the effect
of this accretion on money supply. In previous years this was done by
selling government securities held by the RBI, which reduced the rupee
assets it held in lieu of net credit provided to the government to partly
compensate for the increase in its foreign currency assets. However, as
a result of the overexploitation of this option, the stock of marketable
government securities held by the RBI had collapsed from Rs. 1,16,444
crore on March 31, 2003 to Rs. 44,217 crore on March 31 2004, and has
declined even further since.
This called for a change in track when seeking to manage the effects of
reserve accretion. In the event, the RBI and the government signed an
Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) to launch as of April 2004 a Market
Stabilisation Scheme(MSS). Under the scheme, the government issued treasury
bills in the open market in excess of it normal borrowing requirements
to draw in cash and suck out liquidity from the system. The interest due
on those securities was to be paid by the government with budgetary resources.
The bills were rendered attractive by making them eligible for use to
achieve stipulated statutory liquidity ratio (SLR) requirements and for
sale under the repo scheme to obtain additional resources.
The amounts raised by the government under the MSS are held with the RBI
in a cash account. Since this cash cannot be used by the government for
its expenditure it helps reduce liquidity in the system. However, the
process involves a cost, inasmuch as the interest payable on these securities
is financed through the budget. The government is paying a price to ensure
that that the capital surge does not result in a runaway increase in liquidity.
In addition to this the RBI has used the reverse repurchase option to
reduce liquidity as and when required. In this case government securities
are handed over by the RBI to the banks at a discount to be repurchased
at par later. In the interim the RBI is drawing down its assets to ensure
a corresponding reduction in liquidity in the system. The increase in
the reverse repo rate announced in the monetary policy statement is partly
meant to facilitate this operation, by making the practice of parking
funds with the RBI more attractive for the banks. Here too the RBI pays
a price to sterilise theffects oif reserve accretion.
It is through such activities that the central bank has been able to deal
with the challenge of excess liquidity created by the accretion of excess
foreign reserves. But this implies that dollars flowing into the country
and earning relatively high rates of return in dollar terms end up in
the hands of the central bank, which parks them at extremely low rates
of interest in liquid investment, including US government Treasury Bills.
The difference in the rate of return earned on the inflow by foreigners
and that earned by the RBI on its investments constitute a net foreign
exchange outflow from the country.
Needless to say, the RBI has been forced to resort to these measures because
the Finance Ministry has rejected the option of restricting capital inflows,
undermining in the process the so call independence of the central bank.
All that the RBI Governor has been able to do in the circumstances is
to tangentially point to elements of fragility in the current situation.
While announcing the policy, he said: ''Domestic factors dominate today
and they ensure stability. Global factors point to risk.''
|