The
leaders of organised manufacturing in India complain much. About
intrusive government, inadequate economic reform, overly high taxation,
inflexible labour markets and much else. Even if there is an element
of truth in any or all of these, this does not seem to have affected
the sector's ability to garner higher profits in the years after
liberalisation. The sector seems to have done extremely well for
itself since the early 1990s.
Consider trends emerging from the official Annual Survey of Industries
relating to the organised manufacturing sector depicted in the accompanying
chart.
To start with, since the early 1990s, when liberalisation opened
the doors to investment and permitted much freer import of technology
and equipment from abroad, productivity in organised manufacturing
has been almost continuously rising. Net value added (or the excess
of output values over input costs and depreciation) per employed
worker measured in constant 2004-05 prices (represented by the green
line), rose from a little over Rs. 1 lakh to more than Rs. 5 lakh.
That is, productivity as measured by net product per worker adjusted
for inflation registered a close to five-fold increase over this
30-year period. And more than three-fourths of that increase came
after the early 1990s.
Unfortunately for labour, and fortunately for capital, the benefit
of that productivity increase did not accrue to workers. The average
real wage paid per worker employed in the organised sector, calculated
by adjusting for inflation as measured by the Consumer Price Index
for Industrial Workers [CPI(IW) with 1982 as base], rose from Rs.
8467 a year in 1981-82 to Rs. 10777 in 1989-90 and then fluctuated
around that level till 2009-10. The net result of this stagnancy
in real wages after liberalisation is that the share of the wage
bill in net value added or net product (the blue line), which stood
at more than 30 per cent through the 1980s, declined subsequently
and fell to 11.6 per cent or close to a third of its 1980s level
by 2009-10.
A corollary of the decline in the share of wages in net value added
was of course a rise in the share of profits (red line). However,
the trend in the share of profits is far less regular than that
of the other components in net value added. Between 1981-82 and
1992-93, the ratio of profits to net value added fluctuated between
11.6 per cent and 23.4 per cent. During much of the next decade
(1992-93 to 2002-03) it remained at a significantly higher level,
fluctuating between 20.4 per cent and 34.3 per cent, but showed
clear signs of falling during the recession years 1998-99 to 2001-02.
However, the years after 2001-02 saw the ratio of profit to net
value added soar, from just 24.2 per cent to a peak of 61.8 per
cent in 2007-08. These were indeed the roaring 2000s! Unfortunately
for manufacturing capital, the good days seem to be at an end. There
are signs of the profit boom tapering off and even declining between
2006-07 and 2009-10. But this latter period being short, we need
to wait for more recent ASI figures to arrive at any firm conclusions.
As of now, what needs explaining is the remarkable boom in profits
at the expense of all other components of net value added. An interesting
feature that emerges from the chart is the fact that the ratio of
profits to value of output (violet line), or the margin on sales,
tracks closely the irregular trend in the share of profits in value
added described above. Increases in profit shares have clearly been
the result of a rise in the mark up represented by the profit margin
to sales ratio, or the ability of capital to extract more profit
from every unit of output.
Interestingly, the periods in which the ratio of profits to the
value of output has risen, leading to sharp increases in profit
shares, were also the years when the two post-liberalisation booms
in manufacturing occurred. The first of those was the mini-boom
of the mid-1990s, starting in 1993-94 and going on to 1997-98, which
was fuelled by the pent-up demand in the upper income groups for
a range of goods that had remained unsatisfied prior to the liberalisation
of imports and foreign investment rules. The second was the stronger
and more prolonged boom after 2002-03, led by new sources of demand,
which was arrested by the global financial crisis in 2008-09. The
coincidence of the profit and the output booms suggests that, in
periods of rising demand, the organised manufacturing sector in
India has been able to exploit liberalisation in two ways. First,
it has been able to expand and modernise using imported technologies,
raising labour productivity significantly in the process. Secondly,
it has been able to ensure that the benefit of that productivity
increase accrues almost solely to profit earners, because of the
conditions created by the ''reformed'' economic environment.
As a result, the mark up rose significantly or sharply in these
periods and delivered a profit boom. The evidence is clear. Big
industrial capital has been a major beneficiary of reform. Its complaints
are not to be taken too seriously.
*
This article was originally published in the Hindu, 10 May 2012,
and is available at
http://www.thehindu.com/opinion/columns/Chandrasekhar/article3403450.ece