It has
been broadcast as an impressive, almost spectacular recovery from the
financial crisis. From the beginning of 1999, the South Korean economy
appeared to show extraordinary potential for bouncing back from the
major recession into which it had plunged over 1998. Growth rates of
national output and of industry over the past one and a half years have
been in the region of 8 to 10 per cent, and even though investment has
remained subdued, the stability of the Korean won also suggested
that foreign "investor confidence" had been restored.
But even
in this apparent bull run, serious analysts had already noted tendencies
that were causes for concern. A major impetus for the revival in economic
activity and growth rates was the expansionary fiscal stance, through
very large government deficits that were enabled by Japanese aid in
the form of Miyazawa Plan funds and allowed by a somewhat chastened
IMF. The inflow of foreign direct investment that contributed to the
stability of the won was dominantly in the form of acquisition
of domestic assets by multinational investors at what were described
as "bargain basement" prices.
And most
importantly, the weaknesses of the large industrial giants that were
the backbone of the Korean growth miracle of the preceding decades,
have been more rather than less evident. The chaebol, which are
now much reviled as privileged, opaque, cronyistic and unwieldy monopolistic
conglomerates created by state patronage, were in fact the most significant
elements in an industrialisation process that even dared to shift core-periphery
economic relationships in the latter part of the past century.
Thus, the
Korean chaebol, and in particular the four conglomerates that
were most successful in creating internationally accepted brands - Daewoo,
Samsung, Hyundai and Lucky Goldstar - challenged the traditional division
of labour between metropolitan centres of capital and developing countries
that were at best recipients or objects of such capital. As emerging
and successful multinational companies with a home base in the developing
world, they offered both hope and a threat to the existing international
economic order.
The building
of these conglomerates was the result of strategic industrial policy
that took much from the Japanese example, along with the specific political
economy features of South Korea. Systematic state intervention, especially
in credit allocation, and crucial protection of domestic markets in
the initial growth phase, were important elements of that strategy.
The strong interlinkage between finance and industry that is now being
interrogated, was actually a necessary part of both the high domestic
savings and investment rates that fed the boom, and the rapid expansion
and export success of these companies.
It is now
apparent that many of the current troubles of the chaebol can
be traced not to over-regulation, but to the deregulation
of both industry and finance in the early 1990s in South Korea. The
internal and external financial liberalisation measures of 1992-93 allowed
the chaebol to access cheap finance freely, also because their
impressive sales and export performance made them attractive to many
creditors. This money was used for very ambitious investment in diversification
and expansion, which in turn was possible because of the concomitant
deregulation of industry.
This is
what led during the 1990s to several of the chaebol overextending
themselves in often unrelated activities, or creating huge capacities
in some sectors, which have not been justified by subsequent demand
patterns. The automobile industry is a case in point. Prior to the early
1990s, fairly stringent industrial regulation prevented capacities from
exceeding the combination of (buoyant) domestic and external demand.
But the 1990s witnessed a massive expansion of capacity as the Korean
car producers sought virtually to corner the world market.
Cars were
in fact the main instruments in Daewoos plans to become a major
global player. The story of Daewoo is itself the most absorbing rags
to riches saga of the late twentieth century. The company was founded
by Kim Woo Choong who began his career as a shirt salesman. Aided by
systematic state industrial policy, over thirty years he was able to
build Daewoo into an important multinational company with more than
200,000 employees (half of them abroad) and annual turnover of more
than $60 billion. By the end of the 1990s, Daewoo was involved in a
wide production range spanning goods as unrelated as ships in South
Korea, fertilisers in Vietnam, electronic goods in Europe, and of course
cars.
By the
mid-1990s, Daewoo controlled a quarter of the domestic South Korean
market of around 2 million cars, and was expanding its production capacity
into India, Poland and Romania. At the time, it was difficult to find
an industry analyst or financial expert who could find any fault with
Daewoos aggressive expansion strategy. Of course, once the financial
crisis broke in late 1997, the carpers were quick to arrive, and accusatory
fingers were
pointed at Daewoos unjustified diversification, its
over-accumulation, and its huge debt to equity ratios of around 600
per cent.
The financial
crisis and subsequent recession proved to be the beginning of the end
for the Daewoo conglomerate, as it effectively collapsed under the mountain
of its own bad debts, which finally amounted to more than $80 billion.
Late last year, the chaebol was broken up into 12 separate businesses,
one of the largest of which was Daewoo Motor.
This company,
troubled though it was, was nonetheless one of the most respected corporate
names in South Korea. But it was part of an industry whose troubles
have only mounted in the past three years. The domestic market for cars
has shrunk to 1.5 million, which is less than half the capacity of the
domestic producers alone. The international market has also grown very
slowly, and there have been major moves towards concentration because
of this.
The shake-out has been greatest in South Korea, as
many of the car makers that began the decade with grand ambitions ended
it either under foreign control or swallowed by a rival. Thus, the fledgling
Samsung car brand was acquired by Renault of France. Kia was consumed
by Hyundai Motor, which itself has given up a 10 per cent stake to DaimlerChrysler.
Daewoo was considered for purchase by both General Motors and Ford.
But in September this year, Ford dropped its $7 billion bid for the
company and, allowing Ford and Fiat to come in with a much lower bid.
This triggered
off the final crisis. The crunch, when it came, was ultimately caused
by the Korean state allowing it, even encouraging it , to happen. Thus,
in early November Daewoos creditor banks suggested a "rescue
package" entailing 3,500 job cuts and other severe provisions.
This was rejected by the trade unions, and as a result, on November
8, the chief creditor bank - the state-owned Korea Development Bank
- cut off its supply of loans. This meant that Daewoo was forced to
default on short term debts to its suppliers. As a result, it was declared
bankrupt and put into court receivership.
All this
of course means that any new rescue package will be on terms that are
extremely harsh from the point of view of the company and its workers.
One estimate of potential job loss is as high as 500,000 counting the
impact on Daewoos suppliers as well. If the Ford-Fiat offer was
earlier seen as too predatory, any new offer is likely to be aggressively
carnivorous.
It is not
as if the assets to be picked up are actually valueless. Daewoo Motors
Changwon factory is supposed to be the most efficient in the world.,
and several other of its factories are impressive in terms of state-of-the-art
technology and highly productive workers. It also still has 20 per cent
of the Korean domestic market share. None of these qualities is likely
to prevent these assets from being sold for less than a song, or simply
thrown away and allowed to waste.
What is
worse, is that Daewoo Motor is not alone in facing such tribulation.
The fate of Hyundai Construction - one of the countrys largest
employers - hangs in the balance, as it finds itself unable to meet
the debt service of nearly $1 billion dollars which is due now. Once
again, the tightening of screws by the public sector banks which are
its creditors is the proximate cause of its woes. At the moment it is
being allowed to survive simply because another collapse at this point
might be too much for both political and economic stability.
This is
ironic. The apparent resolve of a supposedly popular government to allow
these crucial companies to collapse, stems from its desire to search
for and keep hold of the Holy Grail of "investor confidence".
But the collapse of these companies not only causes severe pain in terms
of unemployment and negative multiplier effects, it also creates widespread
social and political unrest in a country in which unions and social
movements remain relatively strong.
And this,
in turn, displeases investors and reduces their level of "confidence".
The Seoul stock market has already lost 50 per cent of its value over
the past year, making it the worst performing bourse in the world. The
contradictory effects of the governments desire to placate highly
demanding international capital may explain how this can happen despite
the supposed bouncy recovery of the economy.
In the
process, the challenge to metropolitan capital that was posed by the
emergence of such developing country conglomerates, has been converted
in South Korea into the more familiar (if more depressing) plea for
succour.
|