It
has been some time now since the IMF lost its intellectual credibility,
especially in the developing world. Its policy prescriptions were widely
perceived to be rigid and unimaginative, applying a uniform approach
to very different economies and contexts. They were also completely
outdated even in theoretical terms, based on economic models and principles
that have been refuted not only by more sophisticated heterodox analyses
but also by further developments within neoclassical theory.
What may have been more damning was how out of sync the policies proposed
by the IMF have also been with the reality of economic processes in
developing countries. The 1990s and early 2000s were particularly bad
for the organisation in that respect: their economists and policy advisers
got practically everything wrong in all the emerging market crises they
were called upon to deal with, from Thailand and South Korea to Turkey
to Argentina. In situations in which the crisis has been caused by private
profligacy they called for larger fiscal surpluses; faced with crisis-induced
asset deflation they emphasised high interest rates and tight money
policies; to address downward economic spirals they demanded fiscal
contraction through reductions in public spending.
The countries that recovered clearly did so despite their advice, or
in several cases because they actively pursued different policies. And
the recognition became widespread among governments in the developing
world that IMF loans were too expensive because of the terrible policy
conditions that came with them. So returning IMF loans early became
something of a fashion, led by some Latin American countries.
And of course, for the past few years an even more terrible fate had
befallen the IMF: that of increasing irrelevance. From 2002 onwards,
the IMF, along with the World Bank, became a net recipient of funds
from developing countries, as repayments far exceeded fresh loans. The
developing world turned its attention to dealing with private debt and
bond markets, which is where the action was. Less developed countries
found new sources of aid finance and private investment from other sources,
as China, Southeast Asia and even India to a limited extent, began investing
in other developing countries.
So the IMF has not really been a significant player in the international
economic scene in the recent past, and the reasons for its very existence
were often called into question. Embarrassingly, in this period the
IMF in turn was called to book by its own auditors, for apparently poor
management of its financial resources!
But what is interesting about IMF economists is how thick-skinned and
impervious they appear to be. Not only do they simply ignore the devastating
criticisms from outside that completely undermine their own arguments,
they even ignore their own internal research when it comes up with conclusions
that do not fit with their world view. And they appear to be unconcerned
with the growing evidence that they are both unconnected to reality
and unable to influence it in any productive way.
Such intellectual autism is certainly deplorable, but for a while we
did not really need to be too bothered by it any more, since it seemed
to matter so little to the rest of the world what the IMF said or did.
But every crisis is also an opportunity, and the IMF has been quick
to seize on the current global financial crisis as an opportunity to
increase its own influence.
Given its poor record of past incompetence and current irrelevance,
one might imagine that there would be some justified hesitation on its
part, in making grandiose and generalised policy proposals. But that
is too far from what the IMF is used to doing, and so its recent pronouncements
continue in the same hortatory fashion, albeit in a slightly more subdued
and even confused manner.
The most recent World Economic Outlook was released in mid-October this
year, to be presented at a meeting of the IMF that discussed the financial
crisis. What is chiefly remarkable about this report is not just the
continued confidence in its own capacities, but also the very blatant
double standards that the IMF is now openly using for industrial and
developing countries.
In the industrial countries, threatened by economic depression, the
talk has now turned to going beyond monetary measures that do not address
the liquidity trap, to fiscal expansion to revive the flagging economies.
This talk is likely to get louder in the run-up to the Obama administration
in the US, since the New President-Elect has made his own preferences
clear in that respect.
But the record of the IMF in this matter is equally clear: countries
in the midst of financial crisis are supposed to do fiscal contraction,
whether they like it or not. When the government account is in deficit,
it must be reduced or converted into a surplus: when it is already in
surplus, that surplus must be increased. If this is pro-cyclical and
causes the crisis to spread to the real economy and create a sharp downswing,
that is just too bad; this is after all, the “right” medicine and the
necessary pain must be gone through to recover eventually.
In this context, what does the IMF now say about fiscal policy? “Macroeconomic
policies in the advanced economies should aim at supporting activity,
thus helping to break the negative feedback loop between real and financial
conditions, while not losing sight of inflation risks...Discretionary
fiscal stimulus can provide support to growth in the event that downside
risks materialize, provided the stimulus is delivered in a timely manner,
is well targeted, and does not undermine fiscal sustainability.” (IMF,
World Economic Outlook October 2008, page 34, emphasis added.)
So, the IMF completely breaks from all its past practice to recommend
that in this situation the developed countries should engage in countercyclical
fiscal and monetary policies to get out of the crisis. All right, then
what about the developing countries, who have this time been caught
in a crisis that is not of their own making? Oh dear, for them the same
advice is not tenable at all.
Consider the following: “While emerging economies have greater scope
than in the past to use countercyclical fiscal policy should their economic
outlook deteriorate ...this is unlikely to be effective unless confidence
in sustainability has been firmly established and measures are timely
and well targeted. More broadly, general food and fuel subsidies have
become increasingly costly and are inherently inefficient.” In fact,
there is room or tightening on all fronts, both fiscal and monetary!
“Greater restraint on spending growth, including public sector wage
increases, would complement tighter monetary policy, in the face of
rising inflation, which is particularly important in economies with
inflexible exchange regimes.” (page 38, emphasis added)
So, the cards are now all out on the table, and it is clear that they
have been dealt unevenly. And even the rules of the game seem to differ
for the IMF. There is one rule for industrial countries in crisis, no
matter how irresponsible the run-up to the crisis; and another rule
for developing countries, even the most prudent and fiscally “disciplined”
of them.
In fact, this partiality of the IMF even extends to its analysis of
the current crisis, where, bizarrely, the developing countries are held
responsible for some of this mess. “While there is indeed some evidence
that monetary policy may have been too easy at the global level and
that the global economy may have exceeded its collective speed limit,
excessive demand pressures seem to be concentrated in emerging economies
and do not appear egregious at the global level by the standards of
other recent cycles. It is hard to explain the intensity of the recent
stress in financial, housing, and commodity markets purely through these
macroeconomic factors, although they have played some role.” (page 23,
emphasis added.)
Once again, all this would not matter too much if the IMF were to remain
as irrelevant as it has been recently. But now, as the crisis spreads
and engulfs developing countries, and as global credit markets seize
up and create credit crunches, more and more developing and transition
countries are going to need access to liquidity. Already several countries
have lined up for this: Pakistan, Ukraine, Hungary and Iceland. And
once again the IMF is pushing the same disastrous conditions that caused
economic and financial collapse in other emerging markets.
In this context, it is terrifying to hear that European Union governments
are calling for a strengthening of the IMF and even imploring some surplus
countries like China to put more money into the IMF’s coffers. With
its current personnel and ideological framework, such strengthening
of the IMF will only mean that conditions get much worse for the developing
world. The need to examine alternative and less destructive sources
of emergency finance for crisis-affected developing countries is therefore
urgent.