Across the world, attention is focused on the economic
aftermath of the incidents of September 11. What gets missed or underplayed
as a result is the state and direction of movement of individual economies
prior to that date. In India's case, evidence on economic performance
till July 2001, which has recently become available, points to a sharp
deceleration in growth over the first four months (April-July) of this
financial year, which was well before September.
According to the quick estimates of quarterly GDP
growth released by the CSO, the Indian economy had settled at a 6.0
per cent growth rate during the four quarters beginning July-September
2000. However, over the subsequent two quarters, growth slipped to 5
and 3.8 per cent respectively, and stood at 4.4 per cent during the
first quarter (April-June) of 2001-02. This shift to a lower growth
rate of between 4 and 5 per cent over three quarters, is a clear sign
of deceleration.
What is noteworthy is this slide in the pace of growth
has essentially been the result of a deceleration in the growth of the
commodity producing sectors: agriculture and manufacturing. Ever since
the third quarter of 1999-2000 the agricultural sector appears to be
performing extremely poorly, with growth rates of agricultural GDP being
negative in three of the subsequent six quarters and less than one per
cent in two.
In manufacturing on the other hand, starting from
the 7 per cent plus level that GDP growth touched in the second half
of 1999-2000, growth fell to six per cent during the second and third
quarters of 2000-01 and then slumped to 3.5 and 2.3 per cent during
the next two quarters. Going by the Index of Industrial Production,
the slow down in manufacturing has been sharper, with the growth rate
relative to the corresponding period of the previous year falling from
6.2 per cent during April-July 2000 to 2.6 per cent during April-July
2001.
What this suggests is that starved of adequate investments
for more than a decade now, agricultural growth has reached saturation
levels, despite signs of some diversification in terms of crops grown.
Behind the investment slowdown is the stagnation and even decline in
real public investment in the rural sector in general and agriculture
in particular. Given the observed complementarity between public and
private investment in agriculture, with the former known to drive the
latter, the spur to private investment provided by high and rising support
prices for a number of crops has been inadequate to neutralise the basic
tendency towards sluggish capital formation. In the event, despite the
fact that at a generalised, all-India level, monsoons have been normal
or munificent in India for sometime now, agricultural growth has remained
sluggish.
The story in the manufacturing sector is, however,
substantially different. Manufacturing growth has declined largely because
of sluggish demand conditions. There are two ways in which demand for
domestically produced manufactured goods can falter. First, the overall
growth in the domestic market could slow down, reducing the demand for
manufactures. Second, the share of domestic producers in a market of
a given size can decline, because of competition from international
producers.
The first of these factors did play a role in braking
industrial growth, once the post-liberalisation surge in demand for
import-intensive manufactures had been satiated. Not only has the second
half of the 1990s been characterised by some measure of success in the
government's effort to reduce the fiscal deficit in the central
budget, but this has occurred at a time when the tax-GDP ratio has fallen
by close to 2 percentage points. The squeeze in expenditures this reflects
would have substantially dampened the fiscal stimulus that was the prime
driver of industrial demand and growth during the 1980s. With the effects
of the sluggishness in the growth of agricultural incomes noted above
adding to this, it is to be expected that the growth of the home market
would have been constrained. That is, industrial growth is constrained
from the demand side.
Was the impact of this on domestic producers of manufactures
aggravated by competition from abroad in the aftermath of liberalisation?
Till recently the evidence of displacement of domestic production by
imports was anecdotal at best. At the aggregate level, barring the high
growth years 1994-95, 1995-96 and 1996-97, when India's import
bill rose faster than her GDP, the decade of the 1990s was characterised
by relatively small increases and even declines in the value
of non-oil imports in general and non-oil, manufactured imports in particular.
Thus, non-oil import values rose by just 3.2 per cent over 1999-2000
and fell by 8.5 per cent during 2000-01. The sluggishness in non-oil
import values has been consistently used by the government to dismiss
fears of an import surge in the wake of liberalisation. But a closer
look indicates that aggregate, non-oil import values grew slowly not
because of slow growth in the quantum of imports, but
because the effects of an increase in quantities imported on the size
of India's import bill was neutralised by a fall in the unit
values or prices of imports. In fact, the statistical evidence
that India has been the destination for cheaper imports after liberalisation
only corroborates the, often alarmist, "grass roots" view,
that the Indian market is flooded with cheap imports of a range of commodities
from countries like China.
What is more disconcerting is the evidence that the
current deceleration in growth has been accompanied by an increase
in the non-oil import bill. Provisional trade statistics indicate that
during the second quarter of this financial year (June-August), non-oil
imports rose by 16 per cent when compared with the corresponding period
of the previous year, resulting in a 6.8 per cent rise in India's
overall import bill despite a 11 per cent fall in oil imports. Part
of this rise may have been due to an increase in the imports of gold,
since the poor performance of financial markets has rendered investments
in gold attractive. Though commodity-wise import figures for the second
quarter are not yet available, it is reported that the first quarter
of this year (April-June) saw a 33.5 per cent increase in the value
of gold imports from $1.2 billion to $1.6 billion. With gold imports
accounting for about 20 per cent of all non-oil imports, such increases
are bound to affect the overall import bill quite substantially. But
to the extent that this factor alone does not explain recent increases
in non-oil imports, and given the evidence of a decline in the unit
values of many non-oil product imports, the role of import competition
in explaining the deceleration in manufacturing growth could be significant.
With agricultural and industrial growth dampened by
these factors, aggregate GDP growth has managed to touch even the levels
they have in recent quarters only because of the buoyancy of the services
sectors. GDP growth rates in the Financing, Insurance, Real Estate and
Business Services sector has been well above 9 per cent in most recent
quarters, and that in Community, Social and Personal Services fluctuated
between 6.2 and 9.3 per cent. Even in the Trade, Hotels, Transport and
Communications sector, which too has witnessed a deceleration in GDP
growth, the rate of growth has remained above 5 per cent. It is this
resilience in the services sectors that has allowed aggregate GDP growth
to remain in the 4-5 per cent range.
These trends in the pace and pattern of growth in
the Indian economy have two implications that are worth noting. First,
since inadequate public investment and faltering demand explain the
deceleration of growth in the commodity producing sectors, "supply
side" policies cannot trigger a recovery. Hence, arguments that
advocate more and faster reform as the means to trigger a recovery are
completely misplaced. In fact, liberalisation of imports and the fiscal
squeeze associated with reform have been in large part responsible for
the slowdown in growth. What is required for a reversal of the process
is a more aggressive use of tariffs, anti-dumping duties and the like
to deal with unequal competition from abroad. This needs to be combined
with stepped up public investment and expenditure, and an innovative
use of the large food stocks available with the government, to both
increase capital formation as well as stimulate demand. The government
has in recent times espoused such views, but an ideological obsession
with import liberalisation and deficit reduction have prevented the
translation of those views into practice.
The second implication of our analysis of the pace
and pattern of growth is that, given the crucial role of the services
sectors in propping up aggregate growth, any development that adversely
affects the fragile service economy can accelerate the slide in growth.
The events of September 11 and their aftermath have rendered this threat
more real. Given the impact that these developments are having on the
airline industry, the insurance business and the business services and
financial sectors, a sharp slowdown of growth in the services sectors
is more than likely. As a result the artificial prop provided to India's
economic performance by these sectors can give way, converting the slowdown
into a slump. Efforts to revive the commodity producing sectors are
therefore crucial if India's is to deal with the instability that
September's terror attacks have unleashed. But with the government paralysed by its own liberalisation agenda, there are no signs of such
a response as yet.
|