Even as it gets difficult for the IMF to continue to
function in the old way, it is seeking to adapt itself
and the environment to ensure the realization of the
same goals.
The much-shortened annual joint meetings of the
International Monetary Fund and the World Bank were held
in Washington D.C. in September this year, in
circumstances that were not the most propitious. As the
IMF's World Economic Outlook prepared for the
meetings makes clear, in the US, recovery from the
recession that had set in well before the September 11
incidents is losing steam rather quickly, necessitating
a downward revision of the Fund's April projections for
growth in 2002 and 2003. This in turn will only
aggravate the problem of sluggish growth in much of
Europe and the recession in Japan, since exports in both
are significantly dependent on buoyancy in US
markets—therefore, the prognosis for the world economy
is by no means upbeat.
Elsewhere, matters are even worse. The problem of crises
in emerging markets persists, with some of the
'best-behaved' among them, by the IMF's standards, such
as Argentina and Brazil, facing severe or potentially
severe difficulties in both the financial and the real
sectors. Clearly, poor or even dismal economic
performance characterized not only those countries whose
governments had mismanaged their economies, precipitated
a crisis and then turned to the IMF for help. Rather,
countries whose economic management had been declared
exemplary by the IMF were proving even more vulnerable.
This implies that the Bretton Woods institutions are
failing in their self-appointed role as monitors and
managers of the world economic system. This, together
with the fact that the image of the 'efficiency' and
transparency of US markets, long held up as the example
for the rest of the world to follow, has taken a
battering in the wake of an avalanche of revelations of
market manipulation, corporate accounting fraud and
managerial greed, lent credibility to and even validated
much of the criticism of capitalism, the Bretton Woods
institutions and the WTO by anti-globalization
protestors.
These circumstances have forced a response from the
Bretton Woods institutions, which are now struggling to
win developed-country moral, financial and institutional
support for their role as guardians of the world
economic system. This renewed effort at winning
legitimacy was visible in many forms at the annual
meetings held in September.
The most pathetic expression of the desperate search for
legitimacy is the effort to underplay or even deny the
fact that world capitalism is in the midst of one of the
worst crises of performance, confidence and legitimacy,
in the post-war era. This came through in the statement
made by IMF Managing Director Horst Kohler at the
closing press conference to the September meetings, when
he declared: 'We, of course, discussed a lot about the
global economy, and I was encouraged because there was
no doom and gloom discussion, but a differentiated
analysis and some realistic confidence that the recovery
will continue.' Elaborating this point, he said: 'There
is a broad consensus coming from this discussion that
globalization has created unprecedented opportunities to
improve the wealth of nations, and this expression came
not least from the poor and emerging markets. But the
members of the IMF and the World Bank are also aware of
the challenges and risks that come along with it. They
don't want less, but they want better globalization. We
all agree that we must make a conscious and determined
effort to invest in better globalization, to make it
indeed work for the benefit of all.'
Statements like these, however, do not make the problems
go away. Globalization, and the kind of policies
recommended by the IMF and World Bank to countries that
want to benefit from it, has indeed resulted in slow
growth overall and severe crises in particular
countries. There is acceptance now that a shift away
from the IMF's conventional menu of policies may be
needed. One aspect of this shift, which the IMF has
tacitly supported in individual countries, is the
adoption of a reflationary stance with deficit budgets.
Not only is the IMF berating Japan, which has adopted
close to a dozen reflationary initiatives, for not going
far enough, but it has also turned a blind eye to
efforts by crisis-ridden countries to ensure some growth
by hiking the fiscal deficit, as happened in Korea. What
is more, the IMF Managing Director has gone on record
supporting the European Commission's decision to delay
the implementation of the stability conditions agreed
upon as part of the Stability and Growth Pact.
The new need for a degree of ambivalence is also
reflected in the formal changes made at this year's
annual meetings, for the first time since 1979, in the
conditionality guidelines that apply to IMF lending.
According to the IMF: 'Adoption of new guidelines for
conditionality has been motivated by an increasing
recognition of the importance of several interrelated
principles for successful design and implementation of
Fund-supported programs. Chief among these are national
ownership of reform programs, parsimony in the
application of program-related conditions, tailoring of
programs to the member's circumstances, effective
coordination with other multilateral institutions, and
clarity in the specification of conditions.' It should
be clear that 'ownership', of the kind sought to be
achieved through the PRSP process and the Nepad
initiative, is aimed at reducing the Bank–Fund
responsibility for policies that are increasingly
tending to fail, while 'parsimony' and the 'tailoring of
programs to the member's circumstances' are aimed at
giving the IMF and the Bank leeway to permit policies
such as deficit-financed spending in situations where
typical Fund–Bank policies have resulted in a crisis.
But even allowing for lax conditionality, the problem of
crisis even in healthy economies persists, as the
differing experiences in Argentina and Brazil
illustrate. In a candid admission during a visit to
Tokyo, Horst Kohler is reported to have said: 'Recent
experience should also make us even more humble. The
fact that it was not possible to avoid the current
difficulties in Latin America suggests that we still
have a lot to learn.' There are many consequences that
follow from this 'learning experience'. To start with,
despite objections from some members to investing large
sums in rescue packages for countries facing payments
difficulties, the IMF, realizing that whimsical investor
sentiment in the context of elections rather than any
major problem afflicting Brazil's economy explains the
weakness of the Real, has committed a record $30 billion
to help stabilize the Brazilian currency. The message
being sent out is clear. If countries meet their
commitments as part of the global liberalization agenda
promoted by the Fund and the Bank, the IMF should be
ready to help these countries meet international
commitments as and when necessary, independent of
whether such help resolves the basic problem or not. To
that end, the IMF has clearly decided to win support for
mobilizing adequate resources to finance this role. It
is now persuading members 'to consider, at the
appropriate time, an increase in IMF quotas to ensure
that the IMF continues to have the resources to be a
confidence-building anchor for the international
financial system.'
But clearly, the IMF alone cannot carry the burden of
financing these rescue efforts. Unfortunately, in the
view of the IMF, at present the only available mechanism
to deal with countries that have accumulated
unsustainable debt is a bail-out by organizations like
the IMF. The reason why restructuring sovereign debt
rather than IMF-financing of commitments due on
unsustainable debt is proving increasingly difficult was
summarized thus by Anne Krueger, First Deputy Managing
Director of the IMF: 'In the 1980s, restructuring
sovereign debt was a protracted but generally orderly
process. Typically the major creditors were commercial
banks, and they negotiated through a steering committee
of maybe fifteen people holding perhaps 85 per cent of
the debt. … Today we live in an entirely different
world. Since 1980 emerging market bond issues have grown
four times as quickly as syndicated bank loans. With
many banks and bondholders now involved, private
creditors have become increasingly numerous, anonymous,
and difficult to coordinate. The variety of debt
instruments and derivatives in use has also added to the
complexity with which we must deal. Bondholders are more
diverse than banks, and so too are the goals with which
they approach a restructuring… . Individual bondholders
also have more legal leverage than banks and are less
vulnerable to arm-twisting by regulators. No wonder
countries facing severe liquidity problems often go to
extraordinary lengths to avoid restructuring their debts
to foreign and domestic private creditors.'
To deal with this problem, the IMF has been working
towards revising the contractual and statutory
conditions governing international debt. Its proposal
has two components. First, insertion of collective
action clauses that require creditors to come to the
table when the restructuring of debt becomes inevitable.
Second, creation of a Chapter 11 bankruptcy law-type of
formal mechanism 'that would allow a country to request
a temporary standstill on its debts, during which time
the country would negotiate a restructuring with its
creditors. The Fund would only approve such a request if
the debt were judged truly unsustainable, a judgment
that is clearly not an easy one to make. During this
limited period, the country would have to provide
creditors with assurances that money would not be
allowed to flee the country, and that policies were
being put in place to ensure that the country could
repay its debts in the future.'
Difficulties in implementing this proposal are many.
Above all, it would require a uniform domestic
bankruptcy law and enforcement mechanism in every
country, which would be impossible to achieve. However,
the IMF sees a way out: to establish a treaty obligation
by amending the Fund's Articles of Agreement, which
requires the support of three-fifths of its members,
accounting for 85 per cent of the Fund's total voting
power; the majority decision would then be binding on
all members. To realize this goal the IMF requires wide
support from the international community, and that
support is yet to be mobilized—but work on it has
clearly begun.
The objective of this unlikely legal framework is clear.
It helps the IMF help the international financial
system, which, because of its overexposure in some
countries and its atomistic nature, is unlikely to be
able to stall default by working out appropriate
restructuring. In the event, stalling default requires
the IMF to act like a 'lender of last resort', providing
finances to overexposed borrowers with unsustainable
debts to help meet their commitments. But with crises
coming in rapid succession, the IMF is hard put to play
its role. Its far-reaching proposal is thus aimed at
creating conditions in which, despite irrational
practices, the business of finance can continue as
usual, the evidence of overexposure, herd-like behaviour
and moral hazards notwithstanding.
To summarize, even as it gets difficult for the IMF to
continue to function in the old way, it is seeking to
adapt itself and the environment to ensure the
realization of the same goals. This is inevitable, given
the fact that the organization was created and is
sustained by the very interests it extends itself to
support.
|