Despite
six decades of independence, the development project is nowhere near completion
in India. In fact, some elements of that project seem even less likely
to be achieved than in the past, despite fairly rapid economic growth.
This necessarily raises questions about the relationship between the state
and economic development, and requires some assessment of the class character
of the state as well as the kinds of changes this has undergone over this
period.
Taking a long view, there are some clear achievements of the Indian economy
since Independence – most crucially the emergence of a reasonably diversified
economy with an industrial base. The past twenty five years have also
witnessed rates of aggregate GDP growth that are high compared to the
past and also compared with several other parts of the developing world.
This higher aggregate growth has thus far been accompanied by some degree
of macroeconomic stability, with the absence of extreme volatility in
the form of financial crises such as have been evident in several other
emerging markets.
However, there are also some clear failures of this growth process even
from a long run perspective. An important failure is the worrying absence
of structural change, in terms of the ability to shift the labour force
out of low productivity activities, especially in agriculture, to higher
productivity and better remunerated activities. Agriculture continues
to account for around 60 per cent of the work force even though its share
of GDP is now less than 20 per cent. In the past decade, agrarian crisis
across many parts of the country has impacted adversely on the livelihood
of both cultivators and rural workers, yet the generation of more productive
employment outside this sector remains woefully inadequate.
Other major failures are in many ways related to this fundamental failure:
the persistence of widespread poverty; the absence of basic food security
for a significant proportion of the population; the inability to ensure
basic needs of housing, sanitation, adequate health care to the population
as a whole; the continuing inability to ensure universal education; the
sluggish enlargement of access to education and employment across different
social groups and for women in particular. In addition there are problems
caused by the very pattern of growth: aggravated regional imbalances;
greater inequalities in the control over assets and in access to incomes;
dispossession and displacement without adequate compensation and rehabilitation.
Seen in this light, it becomes apparent that a basic feature of the process
of economic development thus far has been exclusion: exclusion from control
over assets; exclusion from the benefits of growth; exclusion from the
impact of physical and social infrastructure expansion; exclusion from
education and from income-generating opportunities. However, exclusion
from these has not meant exclusion from the system as such – rather, those
who are supposedly marginalised or excluded have been affected precisely
because they have been incorporated into market systems.
Thus, peasants facing a crisis of viability of cultivation have been integrated
into a market system that has made them more reliant on purchased inputs
in deregulated markets while becoming more dependent upon volatile output
markets in which state protection is completely inadequate. The growing
army of "self-employed" workers, who now account for more than
half of our work force, have been excluded from paid employment because
of the sheer difficulty of finding jobs, but are nevertheless heavily
involved in commercial activity and exposed to market uncertainties in
the search for livelihood. Those who have been displaced by developmental
projects or other processes and subsequently have not found adequate livelihood
in other activities, are victims of the process of economic integration,
though excluded from the benefits.
This then leads to the question: how is it that an apparently democratic
polity, where there is no question that electoral participation and even
other forms of political voice are entrenched and growing, can continue
to tolerate and even encourage such processes of exclusion? The issue
of the class character of the Indian state is one that has been widely
debated for decades, although in recent times the debate has become more
muddy. One reason for the greater muddiness may be that the simple categorisations
such as "bourgeois-landlord alliance" which were earlier used
with great abandon, are no longer adequate to capture the complexity and
change that characterise these relations. The past two decades have been
particularly dramatic in changing both economic and political landscapes
in ways that reflect dynamic class configurations and social changes.
Therefore, a consideration of the nature of the Indian state must now
incorporate a number of new elements: the entry of finance capital and
its complex relationship with productive capital; the emergence of regional
bourgeoisies with national and even international aspirations; the greater
impact of a new category of capitalists – middlemen in not just finance
but also in trade, arms deals, government procurement and sale of public
assets; the significant role of the middle classes, both urban and rural;
the political and economic impact of the diaspora; the more vocal demands
of social groups that still remain excluded from various economic spoils
of the system; and of course, the essential requirement of legitimisation
which is even more incumbent upon a state subject to electoral democracy.
The sheer complexity of the task of analysing the nature of the current
Indian state does not make it any less urgent. Indeed, such an understanding
is especially important in the current conjuncture when the economy is
entering into a phase which may be characterised as "rampant capitalism".
This phase of rampant capitalism is necessarily dynamic, that is to say
it involves more confident private capitalist activity and creates more
rapid and pervasive effects upon workers and citizens in general. It is
also a phase in which various new forms of primitive accumulation emerge,
as well as the creation of new markets through various means ranging from
the privatisation of public services to the legal enforcement of intellectual
property rights.
To manage such dramatic changes, domestic and international capital may
well desire a more centralised and authoritarian polity which can control
dissent and prevent messy obstructions to this process of rapid accumulation.
Yet socio-economic changes in India are typically too complex to allow
for such straightforward imposition of control. Responses to this can
range from the less desirable forms such as divisive communally inspired
tendencies, caste-based identity politics and regional strife, to the
more progressive democratic movements that force the state to shift the
direction of economic policies and processes to a genuinely more inclusive
pattern of economic development.
|