Since
euphoria over the BSE Sensex breaching one more psychological barrier,
the 8000 mark, preoccupies the media, new signs of economic vulnerability
remain unflagged and ignored. According to the latest trade statistics
released by the Directorate General of Commercial Intelligence and Statistics
relating to the first five months of this financial year (April-August),
the deficit in India's merchandise trade stood at $17431.2 million as
compared with $9728.5 during the corresponding period of the previous
year. This 80 per cent increase in the deficit, if it persists over
the rest of the year, could take India's trade deficit to close to $50
billion over the financial year 2005-06.
It could be argued that such an increase was inevitable given the sharp
increase in the international prices of oil, which was and is expected
to substantially increase India's oil import bill. Indeed, over the
first five months of this financial year, oil imports rose in value
by close to 37 per cent, rising from $12002 million to $16428 million.
However, what is noteworthy is that over the same period non-oil imports
also rose by a similar 37 per cent from $26803 million to $37763 million.
In the event, despite a creditable 23 per cent increase in the dollar
value of India's exports during April-August 2005, the trade deficit
has widened substantially. Even if the increase in the oil import bill
is seen as temporary because oil prices must moderate and even fall,
the same cannot be said of the non-oil import bill. Clearly import liberalisation
has meant that any buoyancy in the economy, even if it is not focussed
on the commodity producing sectors, results in import bill increases
that match those generated by events like the current oil shock. If
that increase has to be moderated or reversed for any reason, lower
economic growth must be the price that has to be paid.
The full significance of this trend comes through when we note that
one comforting feature of India's balance of trade between 2000-01 and
2003-04 has been the surplus on the non-oil merchandise trade account
(see Chart). That surplus helped partially moderate the effects of a
rising oil trade deficit, which rose sharply between 2001-02 and 2004-05,
partly because of a gradual increase in oil prices and partly as a result
of dramatic increases in the domestic consumption of oil and oil products.
However, in 2004-05, the non-oil trade balance was once again negative,
removing the partial cushion offered by the trade in non-oil products
against the effects of a rising oil trade deficit at a time when the
rise in oil prices was sharper. What is happening is that, in a period
when oil prices have registered particularly sharp increases, the non-oil
import bill has kept pace with the oil import bill, resulting in a massive
widening of the deficit on the merchandise trade account.
It is of course true that even during the previous two financial years,
the widening deficit on the trade account was not a cause for concern
because of significant inflows of foreign exchange on account of remittances
and exports of software and IT-enabled serves. According to the Reserve
Bank of India, private transfers brought in a net amount of $20.5 billion
during 2004-05 and software services exports contributed another 16.6
billion dollars. This net inflow went a long way towards financing India's
foreign exchange requirement in that year on account of the merchandise
trade deficit and the deficit under other items of what are termed ''invisibles''.
As a result, the deficit on the current account of the balance of payments
was relatively small. Since India has also been a net recipient of substantial
capital inflows on account of debt and foreign direct and portfolio
investment, this led to a huge accumulation of foreign exchange reserves
that implied a comfortable balance of payments situation.
It now appears that India's relatively strong current account position
is weakening rapidly. As noted above a combination of rising oil prices
and dramatic increases in non-oil imports is resulting in a substantial
widening of the merchandise trade deficit. Simultaneously, there is
evidence that recent increases in remittance inflows are tapering off.
Net remittances, which rose from $16.4 billion in 2002-03 to $22.6 billion
in 2003-094, was down to $20.5 billion in 2004-05. While net revenues
from software services, continue their increase from $8.9 billion in
2002-03 to $11.8 billion in 003-04 and $16.6 billion in 2004-05, the
current account can be expected to widen because of the other two developments.
Consequently, a greater share of the net capital flows that India attracts
in the form of debt and foreign direct and portfolio investment would
now be needed to finance the current account deficit. This would be
perfectly acceptable if these capital inflows were being used to build
productive capacities that can support exports and earn the foreign
exchange needed to meet future foreign repayment commitments that today's
inflows imply. That, however, is clearly not happening. Portfolio flows
create no additional capacities, though FII investments drive the current
stock market boom and create the euphoria that explains the lack of
concern about potential external vulnerability. And to the extent that
foreign debt and direct investment inflows are indeed creating new capacities,
they are not generating export revenues to finance the rising non-oil
and oil import bill.
This is not surprising. It has been clear for some time now that unlike
what occurred in the late 1980s and early 1990s in second-tier East
Asian industrialisers like Thailand and Malaysia, and very much unlike
what has been happening in China for close to a decade-and-a-half now,
''non-financial'' investments financed with foreign capital in India
have not been directed at greenfield projects that contribute to an
expansion of exports. Rather, they have principally been: (i) directed
at increasing the share of foreigners in firms they already control
consequent to the relaxation of ceilings on foreign holdings in domestic
joint ventures catering to the domestic market; (ii) used for acquisitions
of local firms that provide foreign investors with a share in the domestic
market for a range of products; and (iii) concentrated in greenfield
projects in infrastructural services such as power and telecommunications,
which in any case are sectors that produce ''non-tradables'', or services
that are not normally exported to foreign markets.
The only area in which an increase in foreign presence involves export
revenues as a rule is the software and IT-enabled services sector. But
even though export revenues from this sector have been rising rapidly,
the sector is still too small to make up for the foreign exchange profligacy
of the rest of the economy. Overall import liberalisation, combined
with a concentration of incomes in sections of the population with a
significant pent-up demand for imported or import-intensive goods, has
resulted in an excess of demand for foreign exchange relative to current
account earnings.
The incipient tendency towards external vulnerability that this entails
has thus far been ignored for two reasons. First, India's exports have
been performing better in recent years than they did in the past. Second,
India has been such an attractive destination for foreign financial
investors that inadequacy of foreign exchange has become a feature of
a rarely remembered past.
Other than for 2001-02, when India's exports declined marginally, exports
in dollar terms have been rising at over 20 per cent an annum over most
years of this decade. This has been the focus of statements by Commerce
Ministry spokespersons. As and when any reference is made to import
growth, a rise in the import bill is presented more as evidence of recovery
in the industrial sector, rather than as a cause for concern because
that rate has implications for the merchandise trade deficit.
Implicit in this view is the belief that a trade deficit does not matter,
since invisible revenues ensure that a rise in the trade deficit does
not automatically translate into a rise in the current account deficit
and that, even if it does, capital flows are more than adequate to cover
the likely increase in the current account deficit. Recent experience
has shown that the import surge is such that even with reasonable export
growth this view is no longer true. What is more, periodic currency
crises elsewhere in the world suggest that reliance on purely hot money
flows to finance such a current account deficit is by no means a sensible
strategy.
But there is a more fundamental problem here. The success of any liberalisation
strategy depends in the final analysis on the realisation of a rate
of export growth that can deliver growth without balance of payments
problems that are structural. This makes comparisons of the rate of
export growth over time meaningless. Allowing for a reasonable lag,
what is needed is a rate of export growth at any point of time that
covers the increase in imports that liberalisation involves as well
generates the revenues needed to meet commitments associated with capital
inflows. It would be absurd to use more capital inflows to cover past
capital flow commitments, since this involves a spiral of dependence
on capital inflows. Such dependence implies even greater fragility if
such capital flows are of a kind that are footloose and investors can
exit the country with as much enthusiasm as they showed when they entered.
What the evidence on India's trade trends suggest is that even as dependence
on volatile capital flows increases, an export growth rate that is presented
as creditable appears increasingly adequate to cover the import surge
in non-oil imports. Add on a surge in the oil import bill and that inadequacy
is all the greater. This implies that the dependence on volatile flows
to sustain the balance of payments is rising. If the current boom in
the stock market reaches its inevitable peak, then not only will new
capital flows dry up but past capital flows would seek to exit the country.
That is a denouement that must be avoided if India is not to follow
the example of ''emerging markets'' like Mexico, South Korea, Thailand,
Indonesia, Malaysia, Brazil, Turkey and Argentina. If it does, then
it could be the next case where a financial crisis can be the means
to ensure neo-colonial conquest of a country whose elite sees itself
as populating a rising global power.