In
preparing the Approach to the 12th Plan, the Planning
Commission engaged in a wide consultative exercise that
covered different parts of India and involved a varied
group of what are now called ''stakeholders''. The resulting
document clearly indicates some awareness of the complex
problems likely to be faced by the Indian economy in
the coming period. But it falls short of expectations
because it does not provide anything like a cohesive
strategy to deal with these problems, and indeed does
not seem to have a framework that would enable such
a strategy.
Obviously,
it is impossible to consider all the different aspects
of an approach to a plan in this short space. So let
us consider only one of the most central issues in the
economy today: employment generation. This was never
one of the success stories of the macroeconomic strategy
of the reform period: Since the early 1990s, employment
(especially in what could be called minimally desirable
jobs) has not kept pace with the rapidly expanding aggregate
incomes.
The latest large survey data from the NSSO suggest that,
far from improving, the problem has intensified recently.
Between 2004-05 and 2009-10, for all persons above 15,
employment of all kinds (including self-employment,
part-time work, home based work etc) - in terms of
the principal activity - increased at an annual compound
rate of 0.82%, compared to 2.7% in the previous period.
Total female employment actually fell, mostly because
of a massive decline in self-employment. The general
decline in self-employment also calls into question
the future viability of petty self-employment in low
grade manufacturing. Insofar as regular employment of
women has increased, in both urban and rural areas it
has been dominated by ''domestic service'', which can
hardly be seen as a desirable expansion of productive
activity reflecting economic boom.
This is a huge concern, because creation of ''good quality''
jobs is the most important mechanism in making aggregate
economic growth ''inclusive'' as desired, for example,
by the Eleventh Plan. The Approach to the 12th Plan
accepts this point as well: ''For growth to be inclusive
it must create adequate livelihood opportunities and
add to quality employment commensurate with the expectations
of a growing labour force.'' (page 9)
One reason why employment grew more slowly in the most
recent period is actually because of the growing involvement
of young men and women in higher stages of education.
While this is good news, it also means that there will
be more and more young people entering the labour market
with higher level qualifications, expecting to find
employment that is commensurate with their education.
This likelihood too has not escaped the notice of the
Planning Commission; it notes that: ''much larger numbers
of educated youth will be joining the labour force in
increasing numbers during the Twelfth Plan and in the
years beyond. The clear implication of this is that
the pace of job/livelihood creation must be greatly
accelerated.'' (page 10)
However, the problem extends far beyond simply increasing
the aggregate rate of job creation. Much of the increased
enrolment in education has been private: the Approach
Paper notes that private higher education currently
accounts for about four-fifths of enrolment in professional
higher education and one-third overall. Most of these
- especially the professional courses - are associated
with high user fees. Families across the country now
put most of their hopes in educating the young as a
means for social and economic advancement. Where access
to good public educational institutions is limited (which
is increasingly the case) such families educate their
young at enormous cost, selling assets and going into
debt in order to pay the high fees.
Yet it is abundantly clear already that the large bulk
of such private institutions do not live up to their
promise in terms of ensuring employment or even employability.
Examples are rife, of graduates with engineering, management
and other degrees applying for jobs as salespersons
or even railway signalers, because they are unable to
find jobs that will use the skills they are supposed
to have acquired. Some of this is because the system
itself is simply not generating enough of the kinds
of jobs that are demanded by those with such degrees.
But the poor quality of education in many institutions
(both public and private) is also a big part of the
problem.
That is why it is surprising that the Planning Commission
thinks that encouraging more private initiatives in
higher education will solve the problem, and that the
current ''not for profit'' prescription in education needs
to be examined. It is already only too evident - as
the proliferation of teaching shops masquerading as
higher education institutes suggests - that this is
a sector with very strong information asymmetries, where
consumers are often not able to sort out quality or
can do so only after spending long years and often significant
resources in the effort.
In this context, it is chilling to read the argument
that ''free entry will, in the end, automatically weed
out the poor quality institutions'' (page 13). First
of all, how long will it take to ''end''? And in between,
how many lakhs of students and their families will have
plunged into debt and wasted years of their lives? What
will the ensuing frustration and resentment mean for
social stability and potential unrest?
More generally, the Approach Paper does not really seem
to have an employment strategy at all. That may be why,
despite having outlined the problem at the start, there
is no chapter on employment, and the macroeconomic discussion
barely allows this ''soft'' consideration to intrude into
its macho obsession with GDP growth rates. Indeed, despite
all evidence to the contrary, the underlying assumption
seems to be that output growth in itself will generate
the required employment.
Thus, there is a brave declaration that the rate of
job creation in manufacturing should increase to provide
100 million additional jobs by 2025 (page 110). This
is startling, given that economic growth in the fifteen
years up to 2010 generated not even a small fraction
of that number. What makes the projection particularly
brave is that manufacturing employment actually declined
in the period 2005-05 to 2009-10, even though manufacturing
output grew at an annual compound rate of more than
8 per cent over that period.
If manufacturing is to provide even part of the additional
employment that is projected, there must be special
focus on medium, small and micro enterprises. The Approach
document does note the different elements that are required
for this: access to capital and credit; technology and
productivity; marketing and production inputs; creation
of industrial clusters to provide infrastructure. All
of these will require specific policy interventions,
which also take note of the very specific requirements
of women engaged in such activity.
But obviously, if employment is indeed to become a central
goal of economic policy, a more proactive role is required
in general. The first and most obvious requirement is
that employment data should actually be collected at
more frequent intervals. It is extraordinary that reliable
employment data are generated only every five years
through large surveys of the NSSO and every ten years
through the Census, and then made available only after
a very substantial time lag. Compare this to the release
of quarterly data on GDP, which is surely much more
complex to estimate and requires many more assumptions
to be made while deriving the numbers.
If gender-disaggregated data on employment are not collected
and analysed regularly, it becomes impossible to monitor
actual trends or the effects of policies and processes
on employment. Only when such data are available can
it even become a basis for popular mobilization. More
regular (at least annual) data must be the basic minimum
requirement for a government that is serious about employment
creation, and must be an essential demand from the citizenry.
But also, shifting to an employment-oriented macroeconomic
strategy can have many other, more creative aspects.
One aspect that is often missed is the possibility of
using social policy and social expenditure to generate
more employment, which not only improves the quality
of life of people but also has very strong multiplier
effects. Increased public spending on health, sanitation,
education and other essential public services should
be associated with the provision of regular and good
quality jobs in these sectors, rather than exploitation
of underpaid para-professionals who increasingly carry
the burden of service delivery.
This is not only a ''welfare'' measure - it can in fact
be part of a systematic growth strategy, as the experience
of Southeast Asian countries as well as Nordic countries
in the past makes amply clear. This is particularly
important in India at the current juncture because of
our demographic bulge and the increasing numbers of
educated youth in search of productive employment. We
urgently need to redesign our growth strategy with this
viable alternative in focus.
*
This article was published in the Frontline volume 28,
Issue- 20, September 24 - October 07, 2011.