The
allocation of captive coal blocks to private parties
raises a number of issues, of which only one, namely
the loss to the exchequer, because the allocation was
not determined through auctions, has received attention.
Let us first discuss this issue itself, before coming
to others that have been ignored.
The fact that there has been such a loss is so obvious
that the Congress Party's denial of it can only be construed
as an insult to the people's intelligence. The idea
behind allocating captive coal blocks to private parties
is to assure them of coal supplies. They would otherwise
have had to buy the coal they need from, say, Coal India
Limited, at the latter's sale price; instead they now
produce their own coal from the captive blocks given
to them. If the cost of production per unit of coal
is less than this sale price at which they would have
got the coal otherwise, then the profits that would
have accrued to Coal India, if they had been buying
from it, now accrues to them. There is in short a shift
of resources from the public sector to a bunch of favoured
private parties who have the privilege of holding captive
coal blocks.
Since the estimate of the loss can only be made with
reference to a hypothetical alternative scenario, with
which the actual scenario must be compared (in the above
example buying coal from CIL in the absence of having
captive blocks), there will always be some difference
of opinion on the exact magnitude of loss. But this
does not mean an absence of loss. Just as the fact that
there could be a difference of opinion about the magnitude
of the ''drain of wealth'' in colonial times from India
to Britain does not negate the reality of the ''drain'',
likewise quibbles over the estimated magnitude of loss
cannot obscure the reality of the loss to the exchequer.
Manmohan Singh's statement to the parliament, while
careful not to claim ''zero loss'', simply introduced
a lot of red herrings: its aim was to obfuscate the
issue and throw mud at the CAG's report. But his arguments
were utterly specious. He claimed, for instance, that
the CAG had not taken into account the 26 percent tax
on profits that the captive coal block owners would
be paying on mining profits, for local area development,
under the Mining and Minerals Development and Regulation
Bill, which is currently with the parliament. But this
argument is flawed for many reasons: one, the MMDR bill
is still a pie in the sky and the CAG cannot be faulted
for not taking it into account; two, even if 26 percent
of mining profits are taxed away, the logic behind making
captive coal blocks available to private parties makes
sense only in the absence of any profit-making whatsoever
on their part. If private firms make any profits at
all on the captive blocks, then that is an unwarranted
bonanza for them, and hence ipso facto a loss to the
exchequer. Put differently, all profits on mining on
captive blocks should be taxed away and not just 26
percent of profits, and if they are not, then that is
a loss to the exchequer. Three, the fact that Manmohan
Singh at all mentioned the 26 percent proposed taxation,
implies that he was objecting to the magnitude of the
estimated loss, not to the fact of loss itself. But
he was not straight enough to admit the fact of loss.
Not only has there been a loss to the exchequer from
the allocation of coal blocks, but this loss, it is
equally obvious, could have been brought down if the
allocation had been based on auctions. The price of
any asset depends upon the expected stream of earnings
from it that its possession is supposed to yield. In
fact in the absence of speculation, the price of an
asset equals the sum of this stream of earnings discounted
at an appropriate rate of interest. If there are any
profits at all that the possession of captive coal blocks
ensures (and we know that it does), then the auction
price must be positive, which means that the revenue
loss entailed in giving away the captive blocks free
would have been recouped if the blocks had been auctioned.
But it is a mistake to think that the loss to the exchequer
would have been fully recouped if the blocks had been
auctioned. The auction price depends upon the expectations
of those participating in the auction about the future
stream of earnings. Up to 2004, coal prices were in
the range of $25-30 per tonne while the CIL's cost of
production was around $30 per tonne. CIL was in fact
making huge losses in this period. But after 2004, there
was an upsurge in coal prices, because inter alia of
the surge in China's demand, and the price reached $180
per tonne in July 2008, before coming down to the current
level of $100-105 per tonne. Since the extent of future
increase in price would have been underestimated by
those participating in an auction held in 2004 when
the idea was mooted, even the auction price would not
have fully captured the discounted value of the future
stream of profits, and hence the actual loss to the
exchequer arising from the fact that private parties
possess their own captive blocks instead of having to
buy coal from CIL.
The auction route, it follows, is of course far preferable
to merely handing over captive coal blocks to a few
select private parties; but the auction route does not
recoup the entire loss to the exchequer on account of
handing coal blocks to the private sector. This is because
the auction price depends upon the expected stream of
profits, while the loss to the exchequer depends upon
the actual stream of profits. And in a situation where
the latter is greater than the former, the actual loss
to the exchequer exceeds what the auction price can
recoup.
And this brings us to the crux of the issue. We have
to distinguish here between flows and stocks. Coal supplies
every year to the various private parties constitute
a flow. The private parties that need assured coal supplies
really need flows of coal. But by handing over coal
blocks to them, the government is not just assuring
them of flows; it is additionally giving them command
over the entire reserves of coal in those blocks, which
constitute stocks. There is no justification whatsoever
for handing over stocks to private parties whose needs
(and let us assume that these needs are legitimate)
are only for flows.
Put differently, if the government was keen that certain
key coal users should have assured supplies of coal,
and that too let us say at assured prices (though any
such provision of an input like coal at assured prices
would make sense only when there is a corresponding
control over the prices of the final goods produced
by these key users), then it should have simply allowed
these users to enter into supply contracts with Coal
India where such assured supply quantities and prices
were stipulated. This would have meant that while the
key users were assured of coal supplies (and hence the
objective that handing over captive coal blocks to them
is supposed to serve, would have been served), the control
over coal reserves would have remained with Coal India,
a public sector company, and hence with the government.
The government's retaining control over coal reserves
would have enabled it to determine how and at what rate
these should be used, i.e. the flow of output in any
period. Handing over captive coal blocks to key users
implies ipso facto that they would at best produce to
meet their own requirement, but would not produce in
excess of it, even when the country faces a coal shortage,
as indeed it has been doing. It amounts in short to
an arrangement where coal production is institutionally
detached from catering to the scale of national needs.
In fact as Manmohan Singh admitted in his statement
before parliament, several of the holders of captive
coal blocks have not been mining much coal. We have
therefore had an absurd situation where the country
has been importing coal at exorbitant prices, even as
domestic production has been languishing because reserves
have been handed over to private parties for captive
use.
Handing over reserves, whether they are actually mined
or not in any given period, is also a means of nurturing
monopoly. Capturing mineral reserves, as even Lenin
had pointed out a century ago, and thereby keeping potential
rivals away from access to those reserves, has always
been a powerful instrument for buttressing monopoly
positions; and monopoly capitalists often spend massive
amounts for getting this privilege, even when they do
not actually use those reserves for long periods, for
it yields them monopoly profits on the final goods they
produce(which by the way is an additional reason for
the coal block auction price to be positive, i.e. positive
even when there are zero profits in coal production
as such). In India we have the ironic situation where
the government hands over this privilege, of enjoying
exclusive monopoly control over coal reserves and thereby
edging out rivals, completely gratis and free of charge
to a favoured few.
The problem in short began not in 2004; it began in
1993 itself when the whole policy of handing over captive
coal blocks to private parties was introduced. It was
introduced in the name of assuring them of flows of
coal supplies; but it handed over to them stocks, i.e.
reserves of coal completely gratis. The idea that coal
should be developed within the public sector was enshrined
in the second industrial policy resolution of 1956,
which in turn had claimed its lineage from the Directive
Principles of State Policy of the Indian Constitution.
It was an essential component of the Nehruvian policy
and in keeping with the elementary principle that control
over exhaustible resources, whose social use needs to
be planned and carefully calibrated, must vest with
the State. The retreat from that principle, the jettisoning
of the vision enshrined in the second industrial policy
resolution, and the fraud on the Constitution that this
entailed, whereby the nation's precious resources were
simply handed over to private parties in violation of
the Directive Principles, came with neo-liberalism itself
in 1993.
Neo-liberalism however constitutes a fraud not only
on the Constitution but upon its own claims. It claims
legitimacy in the name of ushering in competition, ensuring
a ''level playing field'' among entrepreneurs. But it
actually promotes, as we have seen, monopoly of a few
to the exclusion of others. In focusing on the loss
to the exchequer, we must not lose sight of this larger
loss to the nation.
*
This article was originally published in Peoples' Democracy
2nd September 2012.
|