For
agriculture, the Policy contains a number of measures.
Quantitative restrictions have been lifted on exports
of all commodities except onion and jute. There is
provision for a transport subsidy for exports of fresh
and processed fruits, vegetables, floriculture, poultry,
dairy products and products of wheat and rice. Registration
requirements, which were earlier necessary for farm
exports, have been removed. The minimum export price
condition has been lifted. While these will obviously
reduce bureaucratic delays and assist more exports,
there are questions about how small cultivators facing
large and often monopsonistic distributors would able
to manage in the new scenario in which they are to
face these forces without any element of mediation.
The Commerce Ministry obviously wants to assist the
Food Ministry in getting rid of the embarassingly
large public stocks of foodgrains through more exports.
It is quite happy to assist in a process which will
deprive millions of poor hungry people within India
of access to such grain, in order to push this grain
out as (implictly) subsidised exports. Of course,
this attempt may come up against WTO regulations,
so the Exim Policy proposes an internal transport
subsidy on movement of foodgrain from FCI godowns
to the nearest port, which it believes will bypass
the WTO restrictions.
In
addition to all this, twenty agri-export zones (AEZs)
have been sanctioned, covering mainly horticultural
products. Mr. Maran is clearly a keen promoter of
such zones : past Exim Policies have witnessed the
declaration of various Special Economic Zones. The
13 existing SEZs are also to be allowed to open overseas
banking units, which are effectively offshore banks
free from domestic restrictions such as those on Cash-Reserve
ratio and Statutory Liquidity Ratio. In addition,
they have been promised tax concessions as well.
This over-emphasis on agricultural exports can have
very deleterious consequences for domestic consumption
patterns. Already in the past decade, the rate of
growth of foodgrain production has fallen below the
rate of growth of population, for the first time since
Independence. It is not clear that diversion of cropped
area to cash crops will benefit the poor of the country
or ensure long-term food security of the country.
In fact, the experience of export-oriented agriculture
in Sub-Saharan Africa and its consequences is anything
but inspiring.
Among
the other proposals, "cluster towns" such
as Tirupur, Ludhiana and Panipat are also to be provided
with similar status, in the form of various fiscal
incentives. Thus far, of course, such incentives have
not made much difference to the actual export performance
of these areas or sectors, although they imply quite
a lot of tax revenue foregone in the interests of
providing export incentives.
The other main plank of the new Exim Policy is the
provision of a range of fiscal concessions and tax
sops to exporters under various schemes. Mr. Maran
has probably extracted more fiscal sops for exporters
than any previous Commerce Minister, even though export
performance has not displayed any greater dynamism
as a result. Already over the fiscal year just concluded,
the revenue loss from the various export promotion
schemes is estimated to have been as high as Rs. 23,000
crore or more. In 2002-03, rough calculations suggest
that revenue outgo could amount to more than Rs. 27,000
crore, or 60 per cent of budgeted customs duty collection
!
It
is interesting that this has been allowed by the same
Finance Ministry that has prevented increased allocation
for public employment schemes that would have increased
rural employment, provided rural infrastructure and
helped dispose of the excess food stocks. Since revenue
foregone is in budgetary terms analogous to increased
expenditure, this also means that nearly Rs. 30,000
crore which could have been spent on improving infrastructure
conditions even for exporters, has instead been diverted
to lining the pockets of some exporters. The past
experience with such sops suggests that this would
not necessarily lead to increased exports either.
A
salutary example is that of gems and jewellery, an
export sector that has been a major recipient of fiscal
and trade policy sops especially since 1995-96. The
import of pearls and semi-precious stones has been
liberalised essentially to aid exporters in this sector,
who have also received a range of other incentives.
Nevertheless, the export performance has not been
impressive. As Chart 12
shows, while gross exports have increased, net exports
have actually fallen between 1995-96 and 2000-01.
In fact, if imports of gold and silver are included,
then over the past two years this sector has actually
shown a substantial trade deficit in excess of $2
billion annually.
Chart
12 >> Click
to Enlarge
There are many possible
objections to the basic philosophy underlying the
current Exim Policy, not least because it privileges
export growth as the main objective of trade strategy
and as the engine of Indian development. But even
within this dubious aim, the approach adopted by the
Commerce Minister is unlikely to deliver in terms
of improved export performance, given past experience.
Meanwhile the Policy will mean the wastage of thousands
of crores from the public exchequer that could be
used for more productive purposes, including for developing
a really effective and strategic export promotion
policy.