Many
years ago, the economist Charles Kindleberger had identified the
pattern of a financial crisis in his classic work, Manias, Panics and
Crashes. The crisis is the last phase of a cycle which begins with an
initial boom. The upswing usually starts with some change, such as new
markets, new technologies or political transformations. It proceeds
via credit expansion, rising prices - especially of financial assets -
and euphoria. Speculative mania emerge, "as a larger and larger group
of people seeks to become rich without a real understanding of the
processes involved". Eventually, of course, the markets cease rising
and, as a consequence, those who have taken on excessive borrowing
find themselves in distress. This generates other failures, and the
downslide begins. The final phase can become a self-feeding panic,
involving a downward free fall.
But then financial markets are notoriously prone to
cycles; asset markets have always tended to go boom and bust. This in
itself does not necessarily make for major real economic depression
unless there are other deflationary forces operating, or unless the
effects of the financial failures on the real economy are not
counterbalanced by increased spending in some other way. Major
economic depressions do not result from credit cycles in themselves,
but from a complex interplay of real and financial factors that
reinforce each other.
The central message of Keynes, many decades ago, was that such a
downward spiral can be broken by public action. But as Kindleberger
pointed out, in a global economy, such public action depends upon
institutions, power configurations and division of national
responsibilities which cannot be taken for granted to exist.
Thus, deflation can be transmitted across
countries, through trade flows through the movements of private
capital. In the interwar period which gave rise to the Great
Depression, the fears of capital flight and inflation prevented
governments from engaging in expansionary fiscal and monetary
strategies which could have warded off the crisis. This could happen
because in that period there was no clear leader in the capitalist
world, ready to take on both the power and responsibilities associated
with leadership.
Such a leader has to operate at both financial and real levels to
prevent economic collapse. It has to avoid widespread financial
collapse by continuing to provide funds when others are unwilling, and
it must also operate on the real economy, to ensure a continued
expansion of demand and economic activity. This means running large
trade deficits, and ensuring continued and expanding markets for the
exports of countries facing economic difficulties. These duties are in
fact necessary for stable international capitalism.
But the world economy
today has no such leader, despite the clear hegemony of the United
States in both political and economic terms. This makes the current
deflationary pressures - in terms of both financial and real economic
variables - stronger today than they have been at any time since the
Great Depression. A snapshot view of the world economy today reveals a
picture of stagnation and decline that would have been simply
unbelievable even two years ago.
The talk of possible recession has been in the air internationally for
some time now. And of course, after the September 11 attacks on New
York and Washington, the US Government, the IMF and others were quick
to seize on this as the excuse for predicting a future downturn, which
could then be claimed as the adverse fallout of international
terrorism. The truth is of course, that the weakness in the
international economy was already well advanced for some time before
September 2001. In fact, much of the world economy had actually been
experiencing a slowdown or recession for several years before the last
quarter of 2001.
In fact, the most striking feature of international economic trends
during the 1990s was that the US experienced strong growth while most
of the other economies in the world system languished. This was
essentially because confidence in the US dollar had made American
capital markets a haven for the financial investors. This fed a
consumption-led boom within the US, and also caused growing current
balance of payments deficits for the US economy. The current account
deficit of the US reached the record level of $ 450 billion by the end
of 2001.
These trends made the
latter half of the 1990s unique in the history of post-war capitalism
or another reason. In the past the country holding the international
reserve currency did not face any national budget constraint because
it could print money and spend it across the world, since everyone was
willing to accept and hold such money. As a result, the government of
that country routinely resorted to deficit spending to keep the world
economy moving. That is, the US economy played the role of locomotive
of world growth by sustaining deficit-financed spending.
According to one estimate (published by Morgan Stanley) the growth in
US gross domestic product was responsible for about 40 percent of the
cumulative increase in world GDP in the five years ending in mid-2000,
which is twice America’s share of the global economy. In this period,
demand growth in the US was 4.9 per cent per annum compared to 1.8 per
cent in the rest of the world. In other words, US economic expansion
pulled the rest of the world behind it, at least to some extent.
That
process ended some time in late 2000. And with the US engine of growth
slowing down, it meant that other countries - which had been relying
on the huge demand for their exports from the US to keep their own
growth rates positive - were adversely affected. This has been
immediately evident in terms of world trade. WTO figures suggest that
the growth of world trade in volume terms, which was more than 12 per
cent in 2000, was only around 2 per cent in 2001. And when this is
combined with continued deflation in terms of trading prices in world
markets for primary commodities and many manufactured goods, world
trade in value terms was stagnant.
Patterns of output growth and prices in the major economies
The growth patterns in the major developed
industrial countries are crucial indicators of the overall pattern of
the international economy. Chart 1 provides the IMF’s latest
estimates and projections of growth of real GDP. It should be noted
that these estimates, published in December 2001, are already
significantly lower than those published by the IMF just three months
earlier. While the IMF has attributed the decline to the September
terrorist attacks, it could be argued that the earlier estimates were
anyway to optimistic, as many had suggested at the time.
Thus
the United States economy, which had led in terms of growth rates of
more than 4 per cent per annum until 2000, fell to only 1 per cent
growth of real GDP in 2001. In fact, other sources suggest even lower
growth figures for the US for the past year. Industrial output in
particular has been falling for more than a year.
Further, this period of slowing growth
has been accompanied by decelerating and now even declining price
levels, raising a real threat of deflation for the first time since
the Great Depression. Chart 2 gives the IMF estimates of changes in
consumer prices, which suggest that inflation slowed down sharply and
there was deflation in Japan. But other sources point to stronger
tendencies towards deflation even in the US economy.
Figures from the US
Labour Department indicate that while wholesale prices rose by 0.1 per
cent in January 2002, they had fallen a cumulative 2.6 per cent in the
year to January, which was in fact the biggest 12-month drop in half a
century. Similarly, the data on industrial capacity, (only 75 per cent
in January 2002) have been argued to reflect strong productivity
growth, but they also raise concerns about the risk of deflation - a
vicious cycle of falling prices, profits, production and employment.
Business investment in the US fell by nearly 13 per cent in the last
quarter of 2001 compared to the previous year, making it the fourth
consecutive quarter of falling investment.
The European Union was supposed to be recovering from 2000, but the
past year’s growth performance was once again lower, suggesting that
the earlier growth impetus, such as it was, was not sufficient to
raise the dynamism in the European economy. Both the IMF and the OECD
estimates suggest a further deterioration in aggregate growth
performance of the European Union in the coming year.
The
Japanese economy is currently in the weakest position of all the major
capitalist economies. Clearly this economy is in the grip of a classic
deflation, with low output, falling prices and poor expectations
leading to declining levels of investment.
The
Japanese government’s own forecasts show that the economy will not
grow at all in the fiscal year starting in April, with unemployment
continuing to rise, to nearly 6 per cent. In
2001, prices in Japan fell for the third year in a row, which is
unprecedented for a major industrial economy since the 1930s.
Furthermore, net export performance has also worsened. There was a 38
per cent fall in the Japanese trade surplus for 2001, the largest fall
since 1970 and the third successive year of decline.
Accompanying all this has been a strange process of convergence of
unemployment rates, as evident from Chart 3. While Japan had always
been considered a low unemployment economy largely for structural
reasons, it was argued that more “flexible” labour market combined
with greater economic dynamism made rates of open unemployment much
lower in the US than in Western Europe. But Chart 3 shows that over
the recent past, while rates of unemployment have been declining in
Europe (despite less impressive output growth) they have been rising
in both the US and Japan.
What
is the prognosis, given such a combination of forces in the major
economies ? Most analysts have been pessimistic about the prospects of
an early recovery, despite the Bush administration’s efforts to
provide a fiscal stimulus through large tax cuts and increased
spending, especially after September 11. The pessimism ranges from
perceptions that the size of the fiscal stimulus is simply not enough
to provide the kind of stimulus which is required, to the argument
that it has been largely oriented towards tax cuts for large
corporations and the wealthy along with increased military spending,
neither of which have large multiplier effects.
Another view is expressed in a report issued in December 2001 by the
Levy Economics Institute, written by economists Wynne Godley and Alex
Izurieta. This argued that the current recession in the US is
different from earlier recessions because of large structural
imbalances in the US economy. According to them, “the United States
should now be prepared for one of the deepest and most intractable
recessions of the post-World War II period, with no natural process of
recovery in sight unless a large and complex orientation of policy
occurs both here and in the rest of the world. The grounds for
reaching this sombre conclusion are that very large structural
imbalances, with unique characteristics, have been allowed to develop.
These imbalances were always bound to unravel, and it now looks as
though the unraveling is well under way.”
In
Japan, deflation currently poses the greatest threat. Not only have
prices been falling over the past three years, the rate of decline has
been accelerating. Falling prices raise the real level of interest,
which explains why the very loose monetary policy with historically
low nominal interest rates has not implied falling real rates of
interest, This is the classic “liquidity trap” situation. High real
rates of interest in a depressed real economy increase the debt burden
on both the private and public sectors to potentially unsustainable
levels. Over the past decade, the ratio of gross public debt to GDP in
Japan has increased from 61 percent to 131 percent, which is now the
highest level for any OECD country. If debt levels keep rising in this
manner, it is possible that this may lead to a collapse in public
confidence in such debt, which in turn can even lead to an
Argentina-like crisis with soaring interest rates, high inflation and
outright default.
This
means that the attempt to explain the Japanese economic conundrum in
terms of a bloated and opaque banking sector completely misses the
point, since it is the macroeconomic conditions which are creating the
problems in individual banks as well. Certainly it is the case that in
an economy that is already burdened with vast post-bubble debt and a
heavy burden of non-performing loans held by the banking system,
falling prices and consequently rising real interest rates could
result in a spiral of mass bankruptcy, financial contraction and
deepening recession.
So
far the rest of the developed world has tried to ignore the magnitude
of the Japanese economic quagmire, and certainly has not provided any
meaningful assistance. But there can be significant international
implications if the problems get worse, which they seem likely to do
at present. Japanese capital has financed a large portion of the US
international debt. So an implosion on the Tokyo financial markets,
leading to the calling in of funds from the rest of the world, would
have major consequences for the world economy. At the very least this
would certainly prevent a rapid recovery in US financial markets, but
it could have even more devastating financial effects.
Policy choices :
The fiscal stance
One of the more
destructive economic consequences of the downfall of Keynesianism in
mainstream policy discussion has been the conscious rejection of the
fiscal stance as a major means of changing levels of economic
activity. One of the more blatant examples of this has been in the
case of the European Union, in which the Growth and Stability Pact of
the Maastricht Agreement explicitly restricted the ability of member
states to use fiscal deficits to reduce levels of excess capacity and
unemployment.
Nevertheless it is true that the conditions for using fiscal policy in
this manner have changed significantly over the past decade, partly
because of the cross-border mobility of finance, which can play havoc
with domestic attempts to reflate economies, and partly because of
certain other processes. In fact, what is remarkable about the period
since the mid-1990s in particular, is the very different effects that
fiscal policy have had on particular economies, often completely
contrary to received wisdom.
Consider the evidence presented in Charts 4a to 4d. The first point to
not is how the fiscal deficits have been declining quite rapidly as
shares of GDP in all the advanced countries taken as a group, to very
low levels. In fact, in terms of structural deficit (that is,
accounting for the fact that fiscal deficits move with business
cycles, increasing in slumps and declining in booms), the fiscal
deficit in the major advanced economies was less than 2 per cent of
GDP in the latter half of the 1990s and has been less than 1 per cent
thereafter.
In
the United States, the boom was originally led by large increases in
government spending combined with tax cuts. In the mid-1990s, however,
the US, despite being the country with the international reserve
currency, chose to curtail its fiscal deficits initially. And when the
US government was confronted with surpluses in the course of the boom
triggered by private spending, it chose to hand over some part of
those surpluses to the private sector in the form of tax cuts. As
Chart 4b shows, since 1999 the US government budget has been in
surplus (negative deficit indicates surplus).
Nevertheless, the US economy continued to surge ahead in growth
terms over this period. The demand increase was therefore entirely
private sector-led, fuelled by debt-driven household consumption
increases which were inspired by the capital gains made by those
with some direct or indirect investment in stocks and shares. Since
the middle of 2000, however, such capital gains have turned
negative.
However, fiscal policy has responded by becoming more expansionary
only in the very recent past, with expenditure increases of just
under $100 billion being announced in the wake of the terror and
anthrax attacks. Instead, over most of 2001, official policy has
been directed towards a looser monetary policy, with the US Federal
Reserve announcing six interest rate cuts over the course of the
year. However the interest rate cuts alone have done very little to
push the economy out of the current recession.
In
Europe, the attempts at fiscal compression seem to have gone much
further than even the fairly stringent requirements of the Stability
and Growth Pact. Both the actual and structural fiscal deficits
(shown in Chart 4c) since 1998 have been amazingly low, well below
1.5 per cent of GDP, despite the evident recession and the
continuing high level of unemployment. Given the supposed political
domination of Social Democratic parties in most of the government of
Euro area countries, this pattern obviously requires greater
political economy analysis.
But the most striking pattern is that of the Japanese economy (Chart
4d), in which the fiscal stimulus appears to have been used with
much effort but to little effect over the past few years. The
Japanese government budget has moved from the modest surpluses which
characterised the decade until 1985, to very large deficits
amounting in some years to nearly 8 per cent of GDP. These were part
of the efforts to pump-prime the system, along with low nominal
interest rates that have reached near-zero levels. But still they
have not been able to lift the Japanese economy out of the
deflationary spiral.
What do these contrasting fiscal patterns and their even more
contrasting results suggest ? It would be wrong to infer from these
that fiscal policy is not an important means of changing levels of
economic activity in the advanced capitalist economies. However,
these data do suggest that the pattern of fiscal stance, of the kind
of spending and taxation decisions that are made, may be even more
significant than the absolute levels. Crucially, they are important
because they can change levels of employment, and these in turn play
an important role in affecting expectations of economic agents in
the economy.
Thus, in the US economy, the fiscal stance could
be low because the consumption boom was associated with employment
growth which in turn added to higher private spending. Conversely,
in Japan the combination of fiscal stimulus and interest rate cuts
was not sufficient to reverse the trend of declining employment
opportunities. These led to depressed expectations, which in turn
meant that additional incomes tended to be saved to insure against
future job loss, and therefore did not translate into higher
economic activity.
The
role of unemployment and employment growth
Clearly, therefore, it is necessary
to investigate patterns of employment and unemployment in the major
advanced economies more closely. Chart 5 show the unemployment rates
(as per cent of labour force) in the OECD economies, and shows how
in all the major countries except US, unemployment rates have tended
to increase over the latter part of the 1990s.
However, there are substantial differences in definition and
measurement of open unemployment across the OECD, and therefore
Chart 6 presents the standardised data which tries to use similar
definitions. This presents a rather different picture. Thus,
Japanese unemployment rates appear to rise more sharply while
European unemployment rates appear to have fallen slightly.
A
major problem with such data is the growing presence of the
“discouraged worker effect”, whereby potential workers and long term
unemployed (especially but not exclusively women) tend to drop out
of the labour force and therefore disappear from both numerator and
denominator. This problem has been evident in Europe for some time,
but there are indications that it has been growing in the US as well
in recent times. Thus the slight fall in the unemployment rate in
January 2002 from 5.8 per cent to 5.6 per cent, has been widely
attributed to the “discouraged worker effect”.
Because of this, rates of aggregate employment growth may be a
slightly better indicator of labour market conditions than open
unemployment rates. Of course, even these do not give us an idea of
the nature and quality of employment, as most governments
increasingly include a range of part-time and casual employment as
well, which may reflect distressed worker involvement. Nevertheless,
Chart 7 presents the evidence on rates of employment growth in the
major OECD countries.
The picture that emerges is that of fluctuating rates of expansion,
but overall a fairly dismal performance. The other point to note is
that the employment expansion of the US economy is not all that
impressive in comparative perspective, and has been less than 2 per
cent per annum over the past five years on average.
This is confirmed by the rather rough estimates of employment
elasticity of aggregate output (per cent change in employment by per
cent change in real output) that are provided in Chart 8. Once
again, after the early 1990s, the US economy does not emerge as
considerably more dynamic than other OECD countries in terms of
generating more employment. (It should be noted, however, that the
figure of 1 for the European Union for the period 1990-94 is
misleading, for it refers to a period when both output and
employment growth were mildly negative.) In fact, in recent years
the employment elasticity of output growth in the US economy appears
to have been very low.
This points to a major structural weakness of the past growth
pattern, which is likely to have important effects on the prospects
for early recovery in the developed world. As long as basic
employment conditions do not improve, attempts to generate economic
expansion by encouraging private savings and investment – such as in
the form of tax cuts and easy money through low interest rates - are
likely to falter. This is because those in employment are likely to
guard against the possibility of future job loss by saving more
rather than spending more. To counter such a tendency, fiscal
packages have to be not only very large but also explicitly directed
at job creation. This has not been the case so far in either US or
Japan, while in Europe the fiscal stimulus has in any case been
weak.
In
addition to this, there are other reasons why it may be futile to
expect another US-led boom to bring about a recovery in the world
economy once again. After all, the current recession in the US
reflects the collapse of a speculative bubble, and it would be
strange if the economy could immediately create another such bubble
to generate that kind of economic growth.
At
present, the bursting of the bubble involves the corporate sector
cutting back investment because of overcapacity and the household
sector reducing its consumption because it is already financed by
record levels of private debt. A rapid reversal of these tendencies
is not only unlikely, but it would also require additional
international financing, with the rest of the world’s savings once
again rushing in to maintain high levels of US consumption and
economic activity.
An
increase in US growth levels sufficient to lift the world economy
would lead to a further rapid widening of the US balance of payments
deficit, which is already at more than 4.5 percent of GDP. Such a
payments gap would in turn require an increased financial inflow
from the rest of the world to sustain it. But the rest of the world
already provides nearly $2 billion per day in their savings to the
US economy. It is difficult to see how this can be increased in a
wider international context of lower income growth and stagnant
employment generation.
The
prognosis
If
history is any guide, the need for a leader to pull the capitalist
system out of this slump is obvious. It is also clear that the IMF
is too misguided in its policy responses and too small in terms of
its resources, to play the role of lender of last resort. Indeed,
the Bretton Woods institutions have earned such a bad name in the
current crisis that even the London Financial Times has referred to
them as “the gruesome twosome”. But in any case, the amount of
resources required to prevent international financial debacle is
certainly beyond their capacity.
Similarly the world desperately needs a major buyer of last resort.
If the vulnerable economies of Asia, the teetering economies of
Latin America, the oppressed primary exporters of Africa, and the
devastated regions of Eastern Europe are to recover, they must find
markets for their goods in the west. Thus the developed capitalist
countries must increase their imports from such regions dramatically
on order to avoid a more generalised slump. Big trade deficits in
the most prosperous nations are an essential part of a resolution of
the present crisis.
Clearly, the only feasible solution for international capitalism is
concerted expansion, directed by a responsible world “leader” who
would behave in a Kindleberger fashion to organise such an
expansion. But the current international political economy suggests
that such a solution is not feasible or likely at the moment.
Therefore, some sort of major slowdown in world economic activity
does indeed seem likely, and the world economy could be condemned to
a repetition of the widely read history of an earlier depression.
Of
course, that particular depression did also mark the first
systematic attempts at industrialisation in a range of
underdeveloped countries across three continents. In fact a reading
of history tells us that periods of instability and confusion in the
world economy are precisely those periods which also allow for some
autonomous industrialisation in what has been called the Third
World. So, while world economic recession is both likely and
potentially painful, it may also represent an opportunity for
governments in developing countries to activate strategies of
autonomous industrialisation. The extent to which this occurs will
of course depend in turn on the various political economy forces
which determine policy in our own countries as well.