On
April 4, the US Department of Commerce succumbed to protectionist pressures
and chose to launch investigations to check whether textile imports
from China were disrupting US markets. US Commerce Secretary, Carlos
Gutierrez, is reported to have said that the decision was the first
step in a process to determine whether the US market for these products
is being disrupted and whether China is playing a role in that disruption.
The immediate excuse was evidence of a sharp rise in the quantum of
imports of certain varieties of Chinese textiles into the US market,
quota restrictions on which under the Multi-Fibre Agreement (MFA) were
lifted as of January 1, 2005. As Table 1 indicates, import increases
during the first quarter of the year in select categories that are controversial
have varied from an excess of 250 per cent to as much as 1600 per cent.
However, there is need for caution when quoting these figures, because
they are growth rates computed on a base kept low by the MFA's quota
regime.
Table
1: Increase in Imports of Specific Categories of Textiles: Jan-March
2005 |
Category |
Volume
Growth (Percentage)
|
|
|
Cotton
Hosiery |
1084
|
Cotton
Knit Shirts, MB |
1003
|
W/G
Knit Blouse |
1499
|
Cotton
Skirts |
1102
|
Cot.M/B
Trousers |
1492
|
W/G
Slacks, etc. |
1612
|
Cotton
Underwear |
408
|
M-MF
Underwear |
260
|
Source:
US Department of Commerce, Preliminary Data.
But
touting such figures, US industry associations have been accusing the
Chinese of dumping to an extent that disrupts the US market and damages
the domestic industry. In the event, they are demanding that the government
should invoke a clause included in China's WTO accession conditions
that permits the US government to restrict import growth to 7.5 per
cent a year till 2008. The Bush government that has recently begun its
second term has been quick to oblige, even though domestic political
pressures are not as overwhelming.
There are, however, a number of reasons to hold that the US response
is either alarmist or orchestrated to justify a protectionist response.
We must recognise that quotas under the MFA, which limited the quantum
of exports into individual segments of the global textile market from
the most competitive textile exporters, had two kinds of effects. First,
it reduced the competition faced by US (domestic) suppliers of textiles
from imports from the most cost-competitive centres of global textile
production, allowing the former to sustain higher levels of output.
Second, it reduced competition between exporters from more and less
competitive locations targeting the same market, by restricting the
volume of exports from more competitive producers.
As a result of these two different forces at play, the lifting of quotas
was expected to have two different effects. One was an increase in the
total quantum of imports of restricted items into individual markets
because of increased imports from all locations that are cost-competitive
relative to domestic suppliers. The second was a re-division of an individual
market among exporters, with more cost-competitive suppliers displacing
less cost-competitive ones in individual segments.
As
Chart 1 makes clear, both these tendencies are visible in the US market.
Considering all items of textile and apparel imports, the US trade balance
report which provides the most comprehensive data, indicates that total
imports into the US market rose by close to 20 per cent in the first
two months of 2005 (relative to the corresponding period of the previous
year) as compared with 8.3 per cent during 2004. Thus the removal of
quotas did result in a substantial increase in imports into the US market
that would have resulted in some displacement of domestic production.
However, the increase in imports from China, which amounted to 60.5
per cent during January-February 2005 as compared with 25.3 per cent
in 2004, was not wholly directed at the displacement of US production.
Rather, increased imports from China were accompanied by a decline or
slowing down of imports from other sources such as Mexico, South Korea,
Hong Kong, Taiwan and Japan. That is, after the removal of quotas, Chinese
imports were outcompeting imports into the US from other sources that
were earlier “protected” by the MFA regime.
This is not to say, however, that China is wiping the floor clean. There
are other countries such as the EU-15, the ASEAN countries and countries
belonging to the Caribbean Basin Initiative (CBI) that have been able
to increase the rate of expansion of their exports. What is disconcerting
however is that the Least Developed Countries (LDCs), which do not receive
the same special benefits as the CBI group in US markets, have seen
a significant decline in the rate of growth of their exports to the
US market. But this may partly be due to the disruption caused by the
tsunami in at least some of these countries, such as Mauritius.
Some of these features are sharper if we consider an area like apparel,
which is where the bulk of the increase in imports into the US from
China has taken place. As Chart 2 indicates, while China's apparel exports
to the US grew by close to 75 per cent during the first two months of
2005, as compared with 23 per cent during 2004, this was accompanied
by a substantial degree of displacement of imports from Canada, Mexico,
South Korea, Hong Kong and Taiwan. Further, besides increases in imports
from country-groupings such as the EU-15, ASEAN and the CBI, LDCs have
registered a much smaller decline in the rate of growth of imports than
is suggested by aggregate figures.
In sum, not all of China's dramatic export increase during the first
quarter of 2005 was on account of the displacement of US production.
It was partly because of displacement of export increases from other
countries. And there were countries other than China which contributed
to the growth in overall textile imports into the US. Above all, as
Table 2 makes clear, the effect of the increase in Chinese exports on
exports to the US from individual developing countries has not been
as adverse as had been expected.
Table
2: US Textile Imports by Country Major Shipper's Report ($ Mill.) |
|
|
|
|
|
Growth
Rate |
|
2003 |
2004 |
Jan-Feb
2004 |
Jan-Feb
2005 |
Jan-Feb
2004 |
Jan-Feb
2005 |
World |
77434 |
83312 |
12284.1 |
14010
|
7.6 |
14.0 |
China |
11608.8 |
14559.9 |
2002.9 |
3362.4
|
25.4 |
67.9 |
Asean |
11678.2 |
12143.6 |
1867.7 |
2014
|
4.0 |
7.8 |
CAFTA |
9244.6 |
9578.6 |
1266.9 |
1408.4
|
3.6 |
11.2 |
EU-15 |
4336.5 |
4530 |
687.5 |
730.9
|
4.5 |
6.3 |
Sub-Sahara |
1534.9 |
1781.8 |
253.2 |
282.5
|
16.1 |
11.6 |
Bangladesh |
1939.4 |
2065.7 |
324.6 |
359.4
|
6.5 |
10.7 |
Cambodia |
1251.2 |
1441.7 |
234.3 |
259.1
|
15.2 |
10.6 |
Fiji |
79.6 |
85.8 |
13.9 |
7.7
|
7.8 |
-44.6 |
India |
3211.5 |
3633.4 |
588.1 |
737
|
13.1 |
25.3 |
Indonesia |
2375.7 |
2620.2 |
445.4 |
477.6
|
10.3 |
7.2 |
Japan |
522.4 |
641.7 |
78.3 |
79.8
|
22.8 |
1.9 |
South
Korea |
2567 |
2579.7 |
393.9 |
344.3
|
0.5 |
-12.6 |
Laos |
3.9 |
2.1 |
0.3 |
0.1
|
-46.2 |
-66.7 |
Malaysia |
737.5 |
764.3 |
117.3 |
109.8
|
3.6 |
-6.4 |
Maldives |
93.7 |
81 |
12.5 |
4.7
|
-13.6 |
-62.4 |
Mauritius |
269.1 |
226.6 |
43.1 |
37.5
|
-15.8 |
-13.0 |
Mexico |
7940.8 |
7793.3 |
1144.9 |
1097.2
|
-1.9 |
-4.2 |
Mongolia |
181.1 |
229.1 |
25.8 |
21.7
|
26.5 |
-15.9 |
Nepal |
155.3 |
130.6 |
25.9 |
16
|
-15.9 |
-38.2 |
Pakistan |
2215.2 |
2546 |
371.4 |
396.9
|
14.9 |
6.9 |
Philippines |
2040.3 |
1938.1 |
323.6 |
299.9
|
-5.0 |
-7.3 |
Singapore |
270.8 |
244.1 |
34.1 |
34.1
|
-9.9 |
0.0 |
Sri
Lanka |
1493 |
1585.2 |
258.6 |
305.5
|
6.2 |
18.1 |
Taiwan |
2185 |
2103.9 |
308.3 |
283.6
|
-3.7 |
-8.0 |
Thailand |
2071.7 |
2198.2 |
314.1 |
372.8
|
6.1 |
18.7 |
Vietnam |
2484.3 |
2719.7 |
361.8 |
430.2
|
9.5 |
18.9 |
What
needs to be noted is that the displacement of US production, to the
extent that it occurred, is a sign that the US has not adequately restructured
its industry during the long years of protection resorted to for this
very purpose. The protection afforded to developed country textile production
with the aim of restructuring those industries began in the 1961, when
the Long Term Agreement on textiles was signed. That agreement provided
the developed countries with a 10-year respite, during which they were
expected to either phase out a part of their uncompetitive textile production,
“burdened” by high wages, or modernise their textile industries to render
them competitive.
The promise to do away with protection in ten years did not materialise.
Protection was continued under the Multi-Fibre Agreement, which was
once more scrutinised for phase-out under the Uruguay Round Agreement
of 1994. But even under that agreement, the phase-out of quotas was
back-loaded, with quotas on close to half of global textile trade kept
in place till January 1, 2005. It is well known that most developed
countries first lifted quotas on items of less relevance to developing
country trade, reserving true liberalisation till the beginning of 2005.
What the first-quarter surge in textile exports to the US indicates
is that despite 45 years of protection expressly justified by the need
to restructure the industry, the US has not done so, unlike countries
such as the UK whose dependence on textiles during the early stages
of their industrialisation was even greater. But the US is not the only
culprit. Even countries in the EU (such as France and Italy) are using
the US resistance to the Chinese export surge as the basis for a demand
for greater protection for their own textile production. The European
Union's trade commissioner, Peter Mandelson, has been resisting pressure
to impose restrictions on Chinese textile imports, on the grounds that
the available evidence of market disruption is inconclusive and could
not justify curbs for the time being. However, his ambivalent postures,
resulting from differences within the Community, suggest that the EU
too might resort to import curbs. Responding to calls from countries
like Sweden not to impose such curbs, since that would amount to protectionism,
Mandelson declared: We should not confuse protection with protectionism.
All this controversy arises despite efforts by China to dampen the growth
of its textile exports since January 2005 to temper the reaction to
likely export increases. In December 2004, China imposed export tariffs
of Rmb0.2-Rmb0.3 per item in some cases and Rmb0.5 per kilogramme in
others in response to concerns in the US and Europe that Chinese textile
exports might surge following the expiry of quotas on January 1. Now,
China is contemplating further export tariffs. Expectations are that
China might raise export tariffs by as much as Rmb2-Rmb4 per piece.
Such action is being contemplated despite the danger that Chinese exporters
are likely to be badly hit, because prices for garment orders are fixed
several months before shipment.
China's need to bend over backwards to placate the US results from three
factors. First, China's own dependence on the US market for exports
that have become a major engine for its growth. Second, the huge trade
and current account deficit on the US balance of payments, which is
resulting in a depreciation of the dollar and rising the spectre of
a financial crash and global recession. Third, the huge US trade deficit
with China that the former wants to reduce by getting China to revalue
its currency. The message is clear, if developing countries record a
deficit on their balance of payments it is their problem and a reflection
of their mismanagement. If the US records a deficit on it external account
that is everybody's problem and a reflection of a global “imbalance”
that needs correction.
Unfortunately, imposing curbs on Chinese textile imports into the US
or the EU may not resolve the problem either of unemployment in the
US and EU textile industries or the deficit on the US trade account.
It would merely serve to increase textile exports from other developing
countries to the US and EU. But the fact that this could be used to
divide developing country exporters and win the support from some of
them in the battle against China may suit the US and EU. It helps win
allies in the battle to force China to turn inwards rather than grow
on the basis of burgeoning exports. Globalisation is good only when
the US-and perhaps the EU-reaps its benefita. If that does not happen,
protectionism or voluntary export restraint is the preferred alternative.