In
2001, prices in Japan fell for the third year in a row,
which is unprecedented for a major industrial economy
since the 1930s. Furthermore, net export performance
has also worsened. There was a 38 per cent fall in the
Japanese trade surplus for 2001, the largest fall since
1970 and the third successive year of decline.
Accompanying all this has been a strange process of
convergence of unemployment rates, as evident from Chart
3. While Japan had always been considered a low unemployment
economy largely for structural reasons, it was argued
that more “flexible” labour market combined with greater
economic dynamism made rates of open unemployment much
lower in the US than in Western Europe. But Chart 3
shows that over the recent past, while rates of unemployment
have been declining in Europe (despite less impressive
output growth) they have been rising in both the US
and Japan.
Chart
3 >>
Click to Enlarge
What is the prognosis, given such a combination of forces
in the major economies ? Most analysts have been pessimistic
about the prospects of an early recovery, despite the
Bush administration’s efforts to provide a fiscal stimulus
through large tax cuts and increased spending, especially
after September 11. The pessimism ranges from perceptions
that the size of the fiscal stimulus is simply not enough
to provide the kind of stimulus which is required, to
the argument that it has been largely oriented towards
tax cuts for large corporations and the wealthy along
with increased military spending, neither of which have
large multiplier effects.
Another view is expressed in a report issued in December
2001 by the Levy Economics Institute, written by economists
Wynne Godley and Alex Izurieta. This argued that the
current recession in the US is different from earlier
recessions because of large structural imbalances in
the US economy. According to them, “the United States
should now be prepared for one of the deepest and most
intractable recessions of the post-World War II period,
with no natural process of recovery in sight unless
a large and complex orientation of policy occurs both
here and in the rest of the world. The grounds for reaching
this sombre conclusion are that very large structural
imbalances, with unique characteristics, have been allowed
to develop. These imbalances were always bound to unravel,
and it now looks as though the unraveling is well under
way.”
In Japan, deflation currently poses the greatest threat.
Not only have prices been falling over the past three
years, the rate of decline has been accelerating. Falling
prices raise the real level of interest, which explains
why the very loose monetary policy with historically
low nominal interest rates has not implied falling real
rates of interest, This is the classic “liquidity trap”
situation. High real rates of interest in a depressed
real economy increase the debt burden on both the private
and public sectors to potentially unsustainable levels.
Over the past decade, the ratio of gross public debt
to GDP in Japan has increased from 61 percent to 131
percent, which is now the highest level for any OECD
country. If debt levels keep rising in this manner,
it is possible that this may lead to a collapse in public
confidence in such debt, which in turn can even lead
to an Argentina-like crisis with soaring interest rates,
high inflation and outright default.
This means that the attempt to explain the Japanese
economic conundrum in terms of a bloated and opaque
banking sector completely misses the point, since it
is the macroeconomic conditions which are creating the
problems in individual banks as well. Certainly it is
the case that in an economy that is already burdened
with vast post-bubble debt and a heavy burden of non-performing
loans held by the banking system, falling prices and
consequently rising real interest rates could result
in a spiral of mass bankruptcy, financial contraction
and deepening recession.
So far the rest of the
developed world has tried to ignore the magnitude of
the Japanese economic quagmire, and certainly has not
provided any meaningful assistance. But there can be
significant international implications if the problems
get worse, which they seem likely to do at present.
Japanese capital has financed a large portion of the
US international debt. So an implosion on the Tokyo
financial markets, leading to the calling in of funds
from the rest of the world, would have major consequences
for the world economy. At the very least this would
certainly prevent a rapid recovery in US financial markets,
but it could have even more devastating financial effects.
Policy choices : The fiscal stance
One of the more destructive economic consequences of
the downfall of Keynesianism in mainstream policy discussion
has been the conscious rejection of the fiscal stance
as a major means of changing levels of economic activity.
One of the more blatant examples of this has been in
the case of the European Union, in which the Growth
and Stability Pact of the Maastricht Agreement explicitly
restricted the ability of member states to use fiscal
deficits to reduce levels of excess capacity and unemployment.
Nevertheless it is true that the conditions for using
fiscal policy in this manner have changed significantly
over the past decade, partly because of the cross-border
mobility of finance, which can play havoc with domestic
attempts to reflate economies, and partly because of
certain other processes. In fact, what is remarkable
about the period since the mid-1990s in particular,
is the very different effects that fiscal policy have
had on particular economies, often completely contrary
to received wisdom.
|