As
usual when the Union Budget is presented, all eyes will be on the Finance
Minister and his speech will be thoroughly scanned for all the implications
on the economy. But this time, there is one particular reason why ordinary
citizens will be specially focussed on the Budget: the hope that the
Government is finally going to act decisively to contain food price
inflation.
It
is not surprising that questions of food security and the right to food
have become such urgent political and social issues in India today.
Rapid aggregate income growth over the past two decades has not addressed
the basic issue of ensuring the food security of the population. Instead,
nutrition indicators have stagnated and per capita calorie consumption
has actually declined, suggesting that the problem of hunger may have
got worse rather than better. So despite apparent material progress
in the last decade, India is one of the worst countries in the world
in terms of hunger among the population, and the number of hungry people
in India is reported by the UN to have increased between the early 1990s
and the mid-2000s.
These very depressing indicators were calculated even before the recent
rise in food prices in India, which is likely to have made matters much
worse. Indeed, the rise in food prices in the past two years has been
higher than any period since the mid-1970s, when such inflation sparked
widespread social unrest and political instability. What is especially
remarkable is that food prices have been rising even when the general
price index (for wholesale prices) has been almost flat; thus, when
the overall inflation rate was only around 1-2 per cent in the past
year, food prices increased by nearly 20 per cent!
Table 1 indicates the price increase in cities averaged across the major
regions, for rice, atta and sugar, which are among the most essential
food items in any household. It is evident that the price increase has
been so rapid as to be alarming especially over the past two years,
with rice prices increasing by nearly half in Northern cities and more
than half in Southern cities. Atta prices have, on average, increased
by around one-fifth from their level of two years ago. The most shocking
increase has been in sugar prices, which have more than doubled across
the country. Other food items, ranging from pulses and dal to milk and
vegetables, have also shown dramatic increase especially in the past
year.
Table
1: Table 1: Retail prices in major cities/towns, by zone. |
|
Average
retail price
on 27.01.10
(in Rupees)
|
Increase
over 1 year
(per cent)
|
Increase
over two years
(per cent)
|
Rice
|
North
Zone |
19.92 |
11.94 |
48.45
|
West Zone |
19.33
|
9.78 |
29.37 |
East Zone |
16.19 |
10.31 |
16.30
|
South Zone |
22.25 |
32.84
|
58.93
|
Atta
|
North
Zone |
17.00 |
24.90 |
24.90 |
West Zone |
17.17
|
15.73
|
21.85 |
East Zone |
17.50 |
19.32
|
22.09
|
South Zone |
20.38 |
5.16
|
13.19
|
Sugar
|
North
Zone |
36.17 |
64.08 |
156.05
|
West Zone |
34.61
|
66.58
|
122.50 |
East Zone |
37.88 |
74.64
|
118.77
|
South Zone |
32.19 |
61.44
|
109.35
|
Source:
Ministry of Food and Civil Supplies, Food Price Monitoring System,
12 February 2010. |
There are many reasons why food prices have risen at such a rapid rate,
and all of them point to major failures of state policy. Domestic food
production has been adversely affected by neoliberal economic policies
that have opened up trade and exposed farmers to volatile international
prices, even as internal support systems have been dismantled and input
prices have been rising continuously. Inadequate agricultural research,
poor extension services, overuse of ground water, and incentives for
unsuitable cropping patterns have caused degeneration of soil quality
and reduced the productivity of land and other inputs. Women farmers,
who constitute a large (and growing) proportion of those tilling the
land, have been deprived of many of the rights of cultivators, ranging
from land titles to access to institutional credit, knowledge and inputs,
and this too has affected the productivity and viability of cultivation.
But
in addition to production, poor distribution, growing concentration
in the market and inadequate public involvement have all been crucial
in allowing food prices to rise in this appalling manner. Successive
governments at the Centre have been reducing the scope of the public
food distribution system, and even now, in the face of the massive increase
in prices, the Central government is delaying the allocation of food
grain for the Above Poverty Line population to the states. This has
prevented the public system from becoming a viable alternative for consumers
and preventing private speculation and hoarding. In addition, allowing
corporate (both domestic and foreign companies) to enter the market
for grains and other food items has led to some increase in concentration
of distribution. This has not been adequately studied, but it has many
adverse implications, including the fact that farmers will benefit less
from period of high prices even as consumers suffer, because the benefit
will be garnered by middlemen.
Thus it has been found that the gap between farm gate and wholesale
prices is widening. A similar story emerges in the gap between wholesale
and retail prices, as evident in the charts. In rice, the gap between
average wholesale and retail prices widened considerably - even doubled
- across the four major zones of the country, as shown in Chart 1. In
wheat (Chart 2), the pattern is more uneven but the retail margins are
very large indeed, as expressed by the difference between the wholesale
price of wheat and the retail price of atta (which is the most basic
first stage of processing).
Sugar is slightly more complicated, as marketing margins appear to show
different trends in different regions and also tend to be significantly
lower than the other major crops. The dramatic increase in sugar prices
is more a reflection of massive policy errors over the past two years,
in terms of supply and domestic price management, and exports and imports.
So
what exactly is happening? It appears that there are forces that are
allowing marketing margins - at both wholesale and retail levels - to
increase. This means that the direct producers, the farmers, do not
get the benefit of the rising prices which consumers in both rural and
urabn areas are forced to pay. The factors behind these increasing retail
margins needs to be studied in much more detail. The role of expectations,
especially in the context of a poor monsoon that was bound to (and did)
affect the kharif harvest adversely, should not be underplayed. But
that refers only to the most recent period of rising prices, whereas
this process has been marked for at least two years now.
In
addition to this, there is also initial evidence that there has been
a process of concentration of crop distribution, as more and more corporate
entities get involved in this activity. Such companies are both national
and multinational. On the basis of international experience, their involvement
in food distribution initially tends to bring down marketing margins
and then leads to their increase as concentration grows. This may have
been the case in certain Indian markets, but this is an area that clearly
merits further examination.
Many people have argued, convincingly, that increased and more stable
food production is the key to food security in the country. This is
certainly true, and it calls for concerted public action for agriculture,
on the basis of many recommendations that have already been made by
the Farmers' Commission and others. But another very important element
cannot be ignored: food distribution. Here too, the recent trends make
it evident that an efficiently functioning and widespread public system
for distributing essential food items is important to prevent retail
margins from rising.
So one major element of the Finance Minister's speech that will certainly
be noticed is the outlay he proposes for the Food Corporation of India.
The UPA government has already pledged to enact a Food Security Bill,
but that needs to be universal in coverage (rather than confined to
Below Poverty Line population) and provide enough volumes to meet minimum
requirements. A universal system of public food distribution provides
economies of scale; it reduces the transaction costs and administrative
hassles involved in ascertaining the target group and making sure it
reaches them; it allows for better public provision because even the
better off groups with more political voice have a stake in making sure
it works well; and it generates greater stability in government plans
for ensuring food production and procurement.
But even before such a law is passed, it is clear that emergency measures
are required to strengthen public food distribution, in addition to
medium-term policies to improve domestic food supply. A properly funded,
efficiently functioning and accountable system of public delivery of
food items through a network of fair price shops and co-operatives is
the best and most cost-effective way of limiting increases in food prices
and ensuring that every citizen has access to enough food.
In a context in which the inflation is concentrated on food prices,
measures like raising the interest rate are counterproductive because
they affect all producers without striking at the heart of the problem.
Instead, if he is serious about curtailing food inflation, the Finance
Minister must provide substantially more funds to enable a proper and
effective public food distribution system.