The
dramatic increase in food inflation over the past two years has been
associated with several surprises. One major surprise has been how the
top economic policy makers in the country have responded to it. The
initial response was one of apparent disbelief, followed very quickly
by the frequently repeated but thus far unsubstantiated conviction that
prices would come down very soon.
Then
this massive increase in the price of essential commodities was welcomed,
even by those who should know better, as being a sign of greater material
prosperity in the country and the success of ''pro-poor'' schemes of
the government, reflected in increased demand for food. Could it be
that the economists who are running the country apparently believed
that food demand should not increase much even in periods of significant
aggregate income growth, and among a population that has the some of
the worst nutrition indicators in the world? Is that why they did not
see any need to work towards increased supply of food and have been
so surprised by even a slight increase in demand?
As it happens, in fact demand for food has been growing much more slowly
than could be anticipated by both income and population growth. Much
of that has to do with the distribution of that growth, which has disproportionately
denied benefits to the poor who would naturally consume more food. But
even so, the fact that it is really the conditions of supply – reflecting
the continuing policy neglect of agriculture as well as the nature of
distribution and the pressures on the market from speculative activity
– that have driven food prices up.
This recognition may be why the official arguments have changed somewhat
recently. Most recently the officially stated position has been to blame
inadequate existing distribution chains – focusing on their inefficiency,
rather than any speculative pressures that could also affect supply.
This has become the most popular interpretation of the ongoing food
crisis in the corridors of power and their stenographers in the financial
press. This has consequently led to the demand that modern corporate
retail chains (ideally with FDI) be brought in to manage food distribution.
As a result, there are now those who have argued that the only solution
to the problem of high food prices is to bring in FDI in retail! It
is argued that this will reduce wastage in storage and costs of transport
of food items, cut out intermediaries in distribution and provide food
more effectively to consumers at lower prices.
Of course this argument is rather foolish, at several levels. First
of all, if the traditional supply chains in food items are so faulty
and deficient, why did they not create such massive food price spikes
earlier? Why was food inflation relatively low in the period until 2006,
despite equally rapid GDP growth and the same system of distribution
that is being faulted?
Secondly, if the problem is inadequate infrastructure, including cold
storage facilities and quicker distribution networks from farm to market,
what stopped the government from more proactive intervention to ensure
better cold storage and other facilities through various incentives
and promotion of more farmers' co-operatives? To announce such measures
only now, as a weak response to a period of raging food inflation is
futile, because obviously such measures operate only with a significant
time lag. This is all the more so because such proposals are explicitly
mentioned in the Farmers' Commission Report, which has been lying with
the government for half a decade now. The idea that cold storage and
other facilities can only be developed by large corporates once they
get directly involved in retail food distribution is ridiculous at best.
Thirdly, this entire argument completely ignores the critical role that
can be played by a public distribution system in moderating such food
price spikes and dampening inflationary expectations and tendencies
of hoarding. Instead of accepting the failure of the government to use
this system effectively so far, the tendency is to throw up hands and
declare that only the large private sector can save us, even though
international evidence indicates that corporate monopoly in food trade
typically increases distribution margins rather than reducing them.
Unfortunately, though, we are forced to take such arguments seriously
because they are being repeated ad nauseum by the media and pushed into
government policies by corporate lobbies. So let us consider what the
recent evidence on distribution margins indicates.
In fact, there is significant reason to believe that the margins between
wholesale and retail prices of many important food items have increased
in the recent period. (See MacroScan, Businessline, 23 February 2010)
The point is that this has been happening in a period of increased corporate
involvement in food distribution and food retail. The share of corporate
retail in food distribution in the country as a whole is estimated to
have tripled in the past four years, and has grown even faster in major
metros and other large cities. And this is also the period when retail
food prices have shown the greatest increase!
The other point that emerges from a comparison of retails margins across
major towns and cities is that such margins are lowest in the states
(like Tamil Nadu and Kerala) where there is an extensive, well-developed
and reasonably efficient system of public distribution that provides
a range of food items on a near universal basis to the population. In
regions where such a public distribution system is weak or non-existent
(such as Utter Pradesh and Bihar) the margins tend to be much higher
and growing faster, even though corporate food retailing in such regions
has been expanding.
So to look at corporate retail as the solution to the current food price
increase is more than irresponsible. There is no question that the current
system of food procurement from farmers is inadequate, faulty and often
quite anti-farmer. There is much that needs to be reformed in the way
that market yards are organised and in the options available to farmers
to get their produce to market. There is a range of necessary and possible
interventions for this, most of which have been stated many times to
the government by various Commissions of its own. Yet thus far the UPA
government has done little about any of these, even in terms of working
with state governments to improve the situation, and instead seems to
think that simply allowing more corporate (and FDI) activity in retail
will allow it to wash its own hands of the matter.
In this context, consider how retail margins have been behaving in the
very recent past, in just one location, the city of Delhi. Charts 1,
2 and 3 describe the price behaviour of three significant but relatively
less perishable food items: rice, sugar and tur dal.
It
is evident that the retail prices have generally been tracking the wholesale
prices in terms of direction of movement, but still there are some noteworthy
variations. On average, retail margins have increased for all these
commodities, and quite sharply for tur dal. This may be the result of
a number of features, and obviously requires more investigation. But
even so it is worth noting that Delhi is a city that has witnssed a
signfiicant increase in corporate food retail. And the role of inflationary
expectations in being able to influence retail price behaviour is obviously
much greater for larger players.
The food prices that have been most talked about of course are those
of onions. Onion prices are widely perceived to have great political
significance, especially in North India. Because onions like other vegetables
are highly perishable, supply conditions should play a major role in
their price. Charts 4 and 5 describe the wholesale and retail prices,
and the total market arrivals of onions and tomatoes in the city of
Delhi.
The evidence is somewhat surprising. For much of the period of falling
market arrivals over the past year, onion prices were rather stable
and the retail margin actually shrank. Prices started rising sharply
only in October – and this is the period after which supply was actually
increasing quite sharply! In November and December, market arrivals
increased but prices continued to shoot up. Surely inflationary expectations
and hoarding must have played roles, along with speculative pressure,
and this was not sufficiently counteracted by public intervention through
its own food distribution network.
The case of tomato prices is similarly interesting. It is evident that
neither wholesale nor retail prices had much relation to market arrivals,
even for this extremely perishable commodity. But what the period of
higher prices has been associated with is a significant increase in
retail margins in October and November.
Dealing systematically with the problem of high food prices in a context
of a largely hungry population should normally be a priority issue for
any government. There are certainly crucial medium term policies that
reverse the longer run neglect of agriculture, that must be implemented.
The issue of rapidly rising cultivation costs that are making farming
unviable once again, needs to be addressed in a holistic way. The concerns
of storage, distribution and post-harvest technology also need to dealt
with. But in the short run, the problem cannot be avoided by talking
of astrologers and the inability of mere humans to predict the future.
Instead, creating a viable and effective public distribution system
that will counteract tendencies to price spikes in essential commodities
is an immediate requirement.