Agriculture,
including activities allied to it, has a rather divergent role in economies
across the world. To start with, there is a great diversity in the share
of agriculture as a percentage of GDP, with the figure varying from
52 percent in Laos, for example, to just 6 percent in Korea. Similar
differences exist with regard to the share of agricultural employment
in total employment. Generally, the lower the GDP, the higher is the
significance of agriculture in the economy. This also means that engaging
in world agricultural trade despite its distortions would have the largest
impact on the poorest countries in the world.
However, the role of trade should not be exaggerated. Though the global
market for agricultural commodities is estimated at $600 billion, the
share of that market serviced through cross-border trade is small. As
Einarsson has argued, there is a basic difference here between staples
and commercial plantation crops.[1] Much of the world’s population obtains
staples from domestic production in their countries of domicile. Of
the staple foods, it is only in wheat that global trade is consistently
above 10 percent of total world production. And only in a few of the
typical plantation crops does global trade represent more than 50 per
cent of world production (Table 1).
Table
1: Approx. share of world production
of selected agricultural products
traded across borders |
Coffee |
80%
|
Tea |
40%
|
Cotton |
30%
|
Soybeans |
30%
|
Sugar |
30%
|
Bananas |
20%
|
Wheat |
17%
|
Feed
grains |
11%
|
Rice |
6% |
Overall,
agricultural trade takes place largely between developed countries,
which account for about 70 percent of both world exports and imports.
Yet, there are three reasons why the level and pattern of global agricultural
trade has important implications for developing countries. To start
with, exports of plantation crops and tropical products of various kinds
are crucial sources of foreign exchange earnings for many developing
countries. This is the group that Tim Groser, the Chairman of the WTO’s
Committee on Agriculture describes as the developing countries with
''offensive'' or ''export'' interests. They ''either already have substantial
economic interests, relative to their economies, in world agriculture
markets and can build on this''; or, ''they can see a future for themselves,
once the massive trade distortions are either eliminated or substantially
reduced.''
The second reason why trade is important for some developing countries
is that they either depend on imports of staples to meet domestic consumption
or their currently prevalent food security is threatened by agricultural
trade liberalisation, inasmuch as cheap imports can result in a sharp
decline in domestic production of staples or the promise of quick profits
may encourage rich farmers and agribusiness interests to ensure or encourage
production of more profitable commercial crops.
Globally, not only is a small share of production of food staples traded,
but exports of food staples are dominated by a very small group of countries
which have been described as "natural exporters", such as
Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, New Zealand, Uruguay, and the
USA. These are countries where favourable geographical conditions, sparse
populations and a very specific experience with colonisation, have encouraged
a large-scale and extensive agriculture that delivers substantial surpluses
of these staples. Production costs here are far lower than elsewhere
making them ''natural exporters''. The only exception to these conditions
among global exporters of staples is Europe, where, as widely recognised,
state support to farmers has been responsible for ensuring the availability
of exportable surpluses.
What is noteworthy is that only a few developing countries that figure
among the group of natural exporters are significant exporters of grains
or animal products. They are Thailand (rice and poultry), Vietnam (rice),
Argentina (wheat, feed grains, soybeans, beef and milk powder), Brazil
(soybeans, beef and poultry) and Uruguay (beef). The net result of this
phenomenon is a peculiar distribution of exporters and importers of
food products between the developed and the developing countries. Over
80 percent of globally traded rice and wheat is imported by developing
countries, as is a sizeable portion of feed grain and soybean exports.
Few developing countries import animal products. The one exception is
powdered milk, a low-value surplus product, of which 85 percent of world
trade goes to the South. And all the high-value animal products such
as beef, pork, poultry and cheese are traded either between developed
countries or from South to North.
Thus in the realm of trade in staples developing countries can be divided
into three rather distinct groups: (i) a small group of exporters, consisting
of "natural exporters" that can compete with developed countries
on the global markets for wheat, feedstuffs and animal products and
a few with higher population densities and more traditional agricultural
structures that are also consistent net exporters, such as Thailand
and Vietnam; (ii) a large majority of developing countries which belong
to a group that thus far has been more or less self-sufficient in food-though
many of these countries may more often buy food from global markets
rather than sell food in those markets, they are not chronically dependent
on food imports and most often are in a position to finance those imports
with foreign exchange revenues from the export of other agricultural
products, typically tropical plantation crops; and (iii) a significant
number of net importers that are chronically dependent on the world
market for basic food supply-many of which are also among the world’s
poorest countries (LDCs).
It is indeed true that over time developing countries have been adjusting
their export profiles depending on trends in global trade. In response
to declines in the prices of tropical products, the middle-income developing
countries have reduced the share of tropical beverages and raw materials-coffee,
tea, cocoa, sugar, cotton and tobacco-in their agricultural exports.
That share has fallen from 55 per cent in the 1960s to 30 per cent by
1999-2001. They have turned to the export of more high value food products-vegetables,
fish, meat, nuts and spices. These now account for more than 50 per
cent of their agricultural exports. However, the financial and technological
requirement for switching over to higher value food crops are clearly
beyond the resources of farmers in the LDCs. Hence, the LDCs as a whole
saw their reliance on raw materials and tropical beverages increase-from
59 per cent in the 1960s to 72 per cent by 1999-2001. In the event,
the pattern of trade dependence of the kind delineated above has only
got accentuated.
These features of agricultural trade imply that changes in agricultural
trade rules relating to staples can affect developing countries in three
different ways. They can increase dependence on imports of staples of
developing countries, since countries that currently do not import but
access adequate supplies through domestic production backed by protection
and support measures would find domestic production displaced by imports.
They could affect the access of the few developing country exporters
to global markets, by allowing for so-called non-trade distorting support
for developed country farmers in the EU and US, which restricts imports
into those regions. They could raise the prices at which those already
dependent on imports of staples can access those commodities. Thus there
is reason to believe that only the few developing countries that are
competitive exporters of staples would wholeheartedly support liberalisation
of trade in staples.
The other group of supporters of a more liberal trade regime would be
the exporters of tropical and non-food products in the export of which
they have an ''offensive'' interest. These countries could believe that
better market access and reduced domestic support in the developed countries
could helps increase the volume of their exports as well as push up
prices.
However, most developing countries would be wary about agricultural
trade liberalisation because of the threat to livelihoods and food security
that the process could imply.
The Asian Experience
All these features of agricultural trade are illustrated by the trade
involved of countries in the Asia-Pacific region. Asian countries are
by no means dominant participants in the world trade in agricultural
products (Table 2). Only one Asian country (China) features among the
top ten global exporters of agricultural products, at rank 9. In fact,
Brazil and China are the only two developing countries among the top
ten. If we consider the set of countries which each account for 1 percent
of world exports of agricultural products, they include the following
from the Asia-Pacific: China, Australia, Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia,
New Zealand and India. Vietnam, Japan, Hong Kong, Rep. of Korea, Chinese
Taipei and Singapore have world market shares between 0.5 percent and
less than 1 percent.
Table
2: Leading Agricultural Exporters
in the Asia-Pacific |
Country |
$
mn |
Mkt
Share |
China |
22158 |
3.3 |
Australia |
16337 |
2.4 |
Thailand |
15081 |
2.2 |
Malaysia |
11061 |
1.6 |
Indonesia |
9942 |
1.5 |
New
Zealand |
9603 |
1.4 |
The
implication of this should be clear: Asia-Pacific countries are by no
means significant influences on global trade and therefore their strength
in global negotiations is by no means substantial. But the reverse is
also true: few Asia-Pacific countries are dependent on agricultural
exports for their export revenues. Chart 1 plots countries according
to their ranks as merchandise exporters and agricultural exporters.
If a country falls along the diagonal (45 degree line) its rank as a
merchandise exporter tallies with its rank as an agricultural exporter.
Interestingly, this is not true of countries that hold the high ranks
in either category, excepting for China. In the case of countries such
as Japan, Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore, they rank high as merchandise
exporters but not as agricultural exporters. That is, the truly successful
Asian exporters have not earned that success based on agricultural exports,
excepting for countries like China. On the other hand, important agricultural
exporters such as Australia, Thailand, Indonesia and New Zealand are
by no means among the top merchandise exporters in Asia.
This could result in a substantial degree of difference in the approach
that countries in the Asia-Pacific region adopt with regard to the trade
negotiations-while exporters like Australia, New Zealand, Thailand and
Vietnam would want substantial liberalisation of agricultural trade
involving all three pillars-market access, domestic support and export
competition-many others may be more interested in limiting agricultural
trade liberalisation in order to protect domestic livelihoods and ensure
food security.
These features of the Asia situation are reflective of differences among
developing countries as a group in the global negotiations, since the
structures of agricultural production and trade at the global level
are the same. Thus if there is still some degree of solidarity in the
developing country camp, it comes from three sources: first, the desire
of the developed countries to protect their agriculture, while demanding
greater agricultural and non-agricultural market access in the developing
countries; second, the belief among developing countries that there
must be adequate safeguard measures especially for ''sensitive'' products
in order to protect livelihoods and ensure food security; and, third,
the conviction that there must be a degree of differential treatment
for developing countries, especially the poorest amongst them.
On the question of developed country protectionism, the evidence is
indeed overwhelming. The OECD report on Agricultural Policies in OECD
Countries: Monitoring and Evaluation released in June 2005 states: ''There
has been little change in the level of producer support since the late
1990s for the OECD as a whole. It has fallen from 37 percent of farm
receipts in 1986-88 to 30 percent in 2002-04, but this level of support
was first reached seven years ago in 1995-97.'' That, we must recall
was almost at the beginning of the implementation of the Uruguay Round.
This constancy in support has been ensured in large part by ''box shifting''
or by the substitution of support measures that are considered trade
distorting, by those that are supposedly not. In 2004, the value of
support to producers in the OECD as a whole is estimated at USD 279
billion or EUR 226 billion. As measured by the percentage PSE, support
accounted for 30 percent of farm receipts, the same level as in 2003.
Including support for general services to agriculture such as research,
infrastructure, inspection, and marketing and promotion, total support
to the agricultural sector was equivalent to 1.2 percent of OECD GDP
in 2004.
This protectionism in the North has helped ensure a degree of solidarity
in the developing country camp. Not surprisingly, G-33 Ministers who
met in Jakarta on 11 and 12 June 2005 to assess the progress of the
agriculture negotiations declared that: ''the problem of food and livelihood
security as well as rural development constitute a concrete expression
of developing countries’ right to development and therefore require
a comprehensive solution in all three pillars of the agriculture negotiations.''
They also ''reiterated that the concepts of Special Products (SP) and
Special Safeguard Mechanism (SSM) as provided for in the July 2004 framework
are fundamental to any meaningful operationalization of Special and
Differential Treatment, and crucial for addressing food and livelihood
security as well as rural development needs of developing countries.
They emphasized that SP and SSM are key policy instruments for securing
the survival of the vast number of small farmers and the rural poor.
Therefore modalities on this matter shall be finalized by the Hong Kong
Ministerial.''
It appears that Tim Groser, the Chairman of the WTO’s Committee on Agriculture,
is sensitive to these demands of the developing countries. He states
in his status report on the agricultural negotiations released on 27
June 2005: ''Many developing countries, and particularly LDCs, have
deeply vulnerable people dependent on agriculture. Integrating these
parts of their agriculture sectors into any emerging reform framework
is deeply sensitive. Such sensitivities have to be accommodated as the
reform process takes shape.''
However, in what is called the ''first approximation'' or the structure
of agreement that has to be arrived at on all three pillars by July
31, 2005 as a basis for the ''political phase'' of discussions from
September to December, he feels that all features of the instruments
designed specifically to take account of the realities of much developing
country agriculture, such as SSM, cannot be addressed.
Past experience suggests that this may not be just a postponement, but
a tactic to delay discussions on issues on which the developed countries
will not give in and then demand that developing countries should be
reasonable and not derail agreement at the Ministerial on account of
such issues. If so, the limited solidarity within the developing country
camp must be used to stall progress along lines that reproduces the
inequities inherent in the Uruguay framework.
[1] Refer Einarsson,
P., 2001 ''The Disagreement on Agriculture''. Seedling 18.