With
the world well into the second year of a recession whose intensity is
unprecedented in the period since the Second World War, two questions
are receiving considerable attention. The first, of course, is whether
the evidence of a decline in the rate of contraction of output and rate
of increase in unemployment in the US, the G7 and elsewhere in the world
is a sign that the recession has touched bottom. The second is whether
there is evidence of a degree of desynchronization of the incidence
and intensity of the crisis across countries. The latter, it is argued,
would help some countries serve as shock-absorbers by reducing the intensity
of the crisis as well as endow the system with sources of growth that
could ensure recovery once the recession has bottomed out. China and
India are two countries that are often referred to in this context.
The case for desynchronization is difficult to make in a globalised
and more integrated world for three reasons. First, globalisation implies
that integration of economies through trade is substantially more than
it used to be so that a downturn in one part of the globe would quickly
transmit itself to other regions and countries. Second, globalisation
results in the creation of multi-country production platforms for various
final goods. This creates international production chains, so that an
increasing share of trade is not the cross-border movement of products
from different industries and activities or even of dissimilar products
from technologically similar industries. Rather a significant part of
trade is intra-industry and involves the movement across borders of
semi-finished products at different stages of processing. When a recession
hits any particular industry and reduces the volume of trade in that
area, the derived demands for the inputs at different stages of the
production chain fall, spreading the effects of the recession globally.
Finally, trade liberalisation has removed quantitative restrictions
and reduced import duties across-the-board in most countries. Depending
on the extent of trade liberalization the relative importance of the
domestic market in driving growth has declined to different degrees
in different countries. This implies that unless countries alter the
degree of protection they resort to, using the domestic market as a
foil against the effects of a decline in trade is difficult to ensure.
And opting for protection at a time of crisis would only invite retaliatory
action from trade partners.
These features of trade in a globalised world imply that desynchronization
leading to some countries serving as shock absorbers and even sources
of stimuli for growth depends on the degree of globalization and liberalization
itself. This in turn implies that assessments of the extent of desynchronization
cannot rely merely on evidence on the differential distribution of the
slowdown in GDP growth or increase in unemployment, but must examine
changes in the rate of growth and pattern of world trade as well.
Trade data at a global level is released with a lag when compared with
data on GDP and in the case of some countries even when compared with
employment and unemployment data. Not surprisingly, it was only in July
that the data on international trade trends during the first quarter
of 2009 in the G7 countries and the world economy was released by the
OECD Secretariat and the World Trade Organization respectively. To recall,
while the slump in production in the developed countries has been with
us since the end of 2007, it was in the last quarter of 2008 and the
first quarter of 2009 that the crisis was most intense. And whatever
evidence we have about the crisis moderating and even possibly bottoming
out comes from the second quarter of the year. So the most recent evidence
on international trade trends relates to the period when the recession
was possibly in its most intensive phase.
As the WTO's World Trade Report 2009 notes: ''Signs of a sharp deterioration
in the global economy were evident in the second half of 2008 and the
first few months of 2009 as world trade flows sagged and production
slumped, first in developed economies and then in developing countries.
Although world trade grew by 2 per cent in volume terms over the course
of 2008, it tapered off in the last six months of the year and was well
down on the 6 per cent volume increase posted in 2007.'' The most important
trend the evidence points to is the sharp contraction in imports into
(and, of course, exports from) the G7 countries (Charts 1 and 2). The
decline in import growth relative to the previous quarter which was
close to 6 per cent in the last quarter of 2008, jumped to 10.5 per
cent in the first quarter of 2009. This trend seems to be generalised
across the G7 (Chart 3).
The
contraction in import growth on a year on year basis was even sharper.
The quarter-on-previous-quarter and year-on-year rates of growth of
imports stood at -9.5 and -23.3 per cent for Germany and -11.8 and -19
per cent in the case of the US. With the G7 countries accounting for
40 per cent of global merchandise imports this must have had a severe
contractionary impact on global economic activity.
The slowdown was not restricted to merchandise trade alone. Compared
with the previous quarter, the value of imports of goods and services
into OECD countries, measured in seasonally adjusted current price US
dollars, dropped significantly in the first quarter of 2009, even if
less sharply then the volume of goods imports. The figure fell by 15.2%.
On a year-on-year basis, the value of imports of goods and services
declined by 27.9%. Thus the sharp drop observed in Q4 2008 continued
in Q1 2009, though in both comparisons, goods fell much more sharply
at about twice the rates than those of services.
The effects of this slowdown on countries like China were visible in
2008 itself. China's merchandise exports in constant prices which grew
by 22 and 19.5 per cent respectively in 2006 and 2007 collapsed to 2.5
per cent. Interestingly the impact on India—a country much less dependent
on merchandise exports for growth—was far less dramatic, with the growth
rates standing at 11, 13 and 7 per cent respectively.
The impact on China's exports was particularly sharp in certain product
categories. Exports of office and telecom equipment fell by 7 per cent
in the fourth quarter of 2008, as compared with the same period of the
previous year. This occurred despite the fact that these exports grew
at an average rate of 17 per cent during the first three quarters of
2008. According to the WTO, exports of this category of items to the
United States ''fell even more sharply, registering a 13 per cent decline
in the fourth quarter (of 2008) after growth of 10 per cent in the third
quarter. Overall, exports of Chinese manufactured goods to the United
States increased just 1 per cent over the previous year, after growth
of 14 per cent in the third quarter.''
This
is significant given the role of this product group in the hi-tech manufacturing
sector in China. In the mid-1980s the hi-tech sector was completely
dominated by the Radio, television and communications equipment sub-sector,
which accounted for almost two-thirds of all hi-tech manufacturing value
added. Since then the production of Office and computing machinery has
been rising rapidly so that by 2005 it accounted for 39 per cent of
hi-tech value added, while that of Radio, television and communications
equipment had fallen to 43 per cent. In sum, information technology
hardware is central to China's hi-tech export success and an important
contributor to incremental manufacturing GDP.
India's production and export structure is different. In part India's
ostensible resilience in the face of the global crisis, reflected in
a much smaller proportionate decline in its GDP in 2008 (1.4 percentage
points on 9.3 percent) relative to China (2.9 percentage points on 11.9
per cent), appears to be because of its much smaller export dependence
on manufacturing. In recent years, India's export dependence has been
much more in knowledge intensive services than manufacturing. But this
per se does not make the country immune to the effects of the global
downturn. World imports of commercial services recorded an increase
in annual growth rates from 12 per cent in 2006 to 18 per cent in 2007,
only to see a decline in that rate to 11 per cent in 2009. And India's
principal market the United States recorded a decline in the rate of
growth of imports of commercial services from 12 per cent in 2006 to
9 per cent in 2007 and further to 7 per cent in 2006. Moreover, India's
interest is in the trade in commercial services (as opposed to transport
and travel services) and here the rates of growth in these three years
were 16, 22 and 10 per cent respectively. That is even the global trade
in services is sharply slowing down in areas in which India has an interest.
Yet this is better than the absolute contraction in the volume of merchandise
imports.
The real point is that exports in general and therefore the exports
of services constitutes a much smaller proportion of GDP in India then
merchandise exports constitute in China's GDP. Hence, it is not India's
less damaging performance in the export area that would count, but the
performance of the domestic market and domestic demand.
Seen in this light, the argument that even if the G7 economies, especially
the US, continue to bounce along the bottom, the global economy can
record a significant recovery because of a return to high growth in
China and India does not seem to have much basis. This would require
in the first instance a sharp shift in China from growth dependent on
external markets to growth dependent on domestic consumption. Secondly,
mechanisms must exist in both China and India for a return to high growth
based on domestic demand, without spurring inflation. And, third this
process must be accompanied by an increase in imports into these countries
from the rest of the world, without destabilizing movements in the balance
of payments and in currency markets, especially in the case of India.
If
this combination of factors does not play out, there is unlikely to
be a return to high growth in these two large economies, which could
help lift the global economy without aggravating preexisting global
imbalances. On the other hand, if there is any revival of growth in
these economies because of a leakage of the demand generated by the
state-financed stimulus being experimented with in the US, UK and elsewhere
in the G7, imbalances both in terms of the global distribution of growth
and the global balance of payments would only intensify. This would
intensify current demands for a dose of protectionism. Not surprisingly,
the World Trade Report from the WTO has among its focal themes, ''the
challenge of ensuring that the channels of trade remain open in the
face of economic adversity.'' This, in its view, requires the design
of ''well-balanced contingency measures'' to deal with a variety of
unanticipated market situations, with ''the right balance between flexibility
and commitments'' in trade agreements. ''If contingency measures are
too easy to use, the agreement will lack credibility. If they are too
hard to use, the agreement may prove unstable as governments soften
their resolve to abide by commitments.'' But the current conjuncture
seems to be one where such balance would be near impossible to achieve.