Once
again food prices have reached exorbitant levels in world trade, surpassing
previous peaks and creating fears of another major global food crisis
of massive proportions. What is particularly shocking this time around
is how little has been learned from the last crisis just a few years
ago, and how criminally slow the international community and national
governments have been to put in place measures that would prevent
a recurrence of these crazy fluctuations in prices.
It is not just that public memory is short - the more worrying feature
is the denial on the part of policy makers about at least some of
the important factors that have caused these dramatic price fluctuations;
and the associated and continued refusal to take measures that will
address the problem. As the last round of food crisis builds up once
again and threatens the lives and material conditions of millions
of people across the world, it is imperative to take a close and hard
look at the evidence on global food prices and their determinants.
One major problem that prevents clarity of understanding on this matter
is the persistent belief that prices in global food markets are still
fundamentally determined by changes in real demand and supply. There
is no doubt that medium to long term trends are drive by this, and
that the expectations that drive speculative behaviour in food markets
are also deeply influenced by perceptions about changes in real demand
and supply. But the pattern of price behaviour in global food markets
in the past few years, and particularly the volatility in prices that
can be observed, bears much less relation to actual supply and demand
shocks, and much more to activity spurred by expectations about prices.
Chart
1 shows the behaviour of global food prices indices since 1990. The
underlying trend for the aggregate food price index is definitely
rising, and this is also true for cereals and edible oils (albeit
to a lesser extent). It is widely accepted that the long years of
policy neglect of agriculture and the agrarian crisis that affected
many developing countries from about the mid 1990s must have had some
impact in not enabling food supply to keep pace with the rising demand
that is also widely perceived to have resulted from the rapid income
growth of some countries with large populations.
However, this conventional interpretation of the food price increase
becomes less convincing when the period is broken down into sub periods.
Charts 2a and 2b show that the period from 1990 to 2005 was quite
different from the subsequent period in terms of food price changes.
In the first period shown in Chart 2a there was some volatility to
be sure, but the overall price trend over the period was if anything
slightly downward. This is despite the same features described earlier
- supply side issues like agrarian crisis in the developing world
and insufficient agricultural investment as well as supposed demand
side forces like more food demand stemming from rising incomes in
low or middle incomes countries - being just as marked in that period,
especially the later part of it.
In fact, the real change in prices comes after 2005, as prices zoom
upwards on a volatile path around a rapidly rising trend. Obviously
something much more was at work in this period than the medium term
''real'' tendencies that were described above. A further issue of
significance that has affected grain prices is the impact of biofuel
subsidies in the US and EU, which have diverted both acreage and maize
production towards ethanol. Since these subsidies became large only
from 2003 onwards, it is to be expected that the impact on grain prices
would be felt after this.
Such a pattern has also prevailed for prices of other food commodities,
as evident from Chart 3. In the medium terms dairy prices have shown
the largest increases, but more recently the big spike has come in
sugar prices.
In previous issues of MacroScan, we have elaborated on the newer forces
that have affected price formation in global food markets, in particular
the involvement of financial players in commodity futures markets,
such that food markets became more and more like other financial asset
markets, plagued with the same problems of asymmetric information,
herd behaviour and extreme volatility. It was shown to have affected
the rapid rise and then fall of commodity prices in the period 2007-09,
as financial agents first moved to and then away from commodity derivatives
during the run up to and eruption of the global financial crisis.
But in the more recent period things have got even more complicated.
Certainly it remains the case that financial activity in commodity
futures markets remains strong and this plays a role in the price
movements. And therefore there is obviously a strong case to be made
for bringing all commodity trading onto regulated exchanges, restricting
the role of purely financial players and enforcing strict position
limits and other such measures.
The measures that have been implemented thus far are unfortunately
halting and inadequate even in the US (which currently has the strongest
such regulations with respect to commodity markets among advanced
countries because of the Dodd-Frank Law). This has meant that in the
context of very low interest rates and few other avenues of profitable
financial investment, the incentives for private players continue
to be loaded in favour of such speculation that can dramatically affect
global prices of these essential items.
Even so, it is increasingly simplistic to suggest that this is all
that is going on and that financial regulation of the kind noted above
would be enough to curtail speculative activity in such markets. This
is because large commodity traders themselves now engage more and
more in what is essentially speculative activity, betting on changes
in prices in order to benefit from these movements even beyond their
requirements of the commodities for ''real'' purposes. The line between
purchases of futures contracts for hedging or speculative purposes
is now almost impossible to draw, especially as large agribusiness
and commodity trading corporations have discovered that there is a
lot of money to be made from purely financial dealings.
This obviously makes the problem of fixing the detail in financial
regulation even more complex, but it also raises the issue of ensuring
that the expectations that are driving such markets are controlled
more effectively. Obviously, addressing issues of global supply -
particularly through ensuring the greater viability of small scale
production in the developing world - is of critical importance in
this.
However,
the sheer volatility of recent price changes around this increasing
trend (as evident from Chart 4) suggests that even addressing
supply issues may not be enough. A related but slightly different
issue relates to the role of information and the nature of its
spread in what are essentially very opaque global markets. This
can be illustrated with reference to food grain markets, and particularly
the global wheat market. Wheat is widely seen as the most significant
traded grain and the role of futures contracts in this market
(particularly through the Chicago Board of Trade) is well-developed.
In the past two years, wheat prices have shown the highest volatility
in terms of monthly price changes. Chart 5 shows how prices of
US wheat nearly doubled in just six months, between June and December
2010, then fell again until early 2011 and then rose once more.
In
terms of ''real'' forces of demand and supply, however, the global
wheat market has been remarkably stable in the past decade. Chart
6 tracks the behaviour of aggregate global production and ''utilisation'',
which can be taken as a proxy for demand, according to FAO data.
In the entire period shown in this chart, both production and
utilisation have increased at average rates of around 2 per cent,
and indeed the rate of increase of production has been slightly
faster than that of utilisation overall.
Clearly, the price changes have borne little relationship to these
two forces. In fact, global wheat prices appear to have risen
in years when supply (production) was higher, often significantly
higher, than demand.
Chart
7 suggests that the price changes in the wheat market have also
had little to do with closing stocks of the same or previous period,
while exports have sometimes (but not always) responded to higher
prices. Of course, it needs to be noted that data on stock holding
is notoriously unreliable. FAO relies on data from governments
on their stock levels, but some governments do not reveal these
data (such as China). Possibly more significantly, there are no
data on private corporate stock holding, and given the size and
spread of multinational companies dealing in grain, this can also
be substantial.
So if it is not actual changes in demand and supply that explain
the price volatility, what is going on? One possibility worth
considering is the considerable role played by rumour, and therefore
by the media, in altering expectations. For example, in the period
from June 2010 when global prices rose sharply, the media were
full of reports about the failure of the harvest in Ukraine, a
major wheat exporter, and then replete with doomsday predictions
following on the export ban in Russia. These certainly drove up
price expectations and pushed up prices in the futures market
very quickly.
Subsequently, FAO data reveal that global production of wheat
had actually increased in this period, largely because of expanded
wheat output in Asia. But the period of sharply rising prices,
while it involved many losers including the poor throughout the
developing world, also had some winners. The large commodity trader
Glencore went for a public stock offering in early 2011, and when
doing so it revealed that it had doubled its profits the previous
years, largely because of gains made in the wheat trade.
Something similar is happening at present - the media are awash
with scaremongering stories about the drought in the US and other
factors affecting global grain supply. Already wheat prices in
the first half of July 2012 have increased by more than 22 per
cent, even though FAP estimates still suggest that globally this
will be a bumper year with a record wheat output. Once again poor
people will suffer because of higher food prices, without even
realising that private profiteering at different levels is generating
that disastrous tendency in global prices.
*
This article was originally published in the Business Line print
edition dated 24th July, 2012.
|