What has happened is that because of the high proportion of term deposits
in commercial banks' deposit portfolios, they are effectively stuck still
paying high rates of interest on a significant part of the deposits.
Meanwhile, depressed investment conditions and the fact that the prime
borrowers now have access to capital from abroad in the form of GDRs, ADRs
and ECBs have implied less demand for credit from the preferred borrowers.
In the circumstances, banks are relying on increasing certain forms of
high-value lending such as consumer credit, and on safe government
securities which offer relatively high rates of return because the
interest rates on most government debt remain high.
Therefore the process seems to be as much demand-driven as anything else,
in terms of banks finding difficulty in identifying desired borrowers at
the prevailing rates of interest. That is why bank holding of government
securities has increased substantially in recent years, rising from 26 per
cent of total deposits at the beginning of the decade to 34 per cent at
the end of the decade. And, as Chart 9 shows, credit deposit ratios have
fallen from the already low levels of the early 1990s, to abysmally low
levels of just above 50 per cent.
Chart 9 >>
This is more than an interesting irony, given the reduction of the
Statutory Liquidity Ratio as part of the financial reforms of the early
1990s. This measure was designed to free commercial banks from necessarily
holding more than one-third of their assets in the form of government
securities, since the SLR was lowered to 26 per cent in 1993. It turns out
that the current position is that commercial banks are holding more than
Rs. 100,000 crore as government securities. This amounts to 35 per cent of
the deposits, which is well in excess of the minimum holding that is
currently required, of 25 per cent. In fact it is the same as the level
that existed prior to the financial reform measures !
At the time when they were first implemented, these financial
liberalisation measures were widely described as working to increase the
access of private borrowers to bank credit. Instead, what appears to have
occurred is that banks are now voluntarily holding government securities
(for which the government is paying much higher interest rates !) and
credit to the private sector appears to have been further reduced in
proportion to deposits. So, while this measure did operate to make
borrowing more expensive for the Central Government and therefore
increased its interest burden, it has certainly not led to greater access
of the private sector to bank credit.
In this context, why then have interest rates not declined in real terms ?
If banks are hard put to find desirable domestic borrowers in a context of
domestic recession, and instead prefer to hold government securities, then
why are real interest rates not driven down further ?
The answer lies in government policy, in a combination of fiscal policy
and financial liberalisation which has put upward pressure on interest
rates and affected the structure of government borrowing. Two financial
liberalisation measures of the early 1990s have been of special
significance in terms of government borrowing.
The first was the decision to reduce and eventually to do away with
deficit financing as a means of financing the fiscal deficit. It is
impossible to justify this in rational economic terms, especially given
the widespread recognition that some amount of deficit financing (which is
the cheapest form of borrowing available to the government) has no
inflationary implications. The second was the reduction of the Statutory
Liquidity Ratio, which was already mentioned.
Both of these measures had the effect of forcing the government into more
expensive open market borrowing, which in turn has been a significant
cause of the increase in the interest burden of the Central Government.
Meanwhile, the increasing resource crunch faced by the State Governments
has also forced them into more market borrowing on even more expensive
terms, since they are seen as less preferred borrowers than the Central
Government.
Indeed, while many complain that the problem is that of the past burden of
public debt, a major problem is actually that of higher interest rates on
public borrowing. These have contributed to a situation which is now
perilously close to that of Ponzi finance, in which the government is
borrowing mainly in order to pay interest.
With this background, the interest rate structure of Central Government
debt becomes absolutely crucial in determining the overall level of
interest rates. While interest rates on government debt have been reduced
in the recent past, real rates remain high. It could even be suggested
that these high real interest rates provided by the government have become
necessary to shore up the banking system in the current recessionary
atmosphere.
The problem is that this is not just an issue of fiscal and monetary
management. It amounts to a huge burden on present and future taxpayers
and potential recipients of public services which are cut because of
resource constraints, given the large drain on the public exchequer
because of interest payments.
This need to maintain high real interest rates in turn becomes necessary
because the other aspect of financial liberalisation has meant that the
government must necessarily be concerned with the need to attract or
maintain capital in the country and prevent capital flight. Thus financial
liberalisation, far from reducing real interest rates, has been the major
contributory factor to their remaining at high levels.
|