On
April 23, India's foreign exchange reserves stood close to $118 billion.
This implies that during the first three weeks or so of financial year
2004-05, reserves had risen by around $5 billion. This reflects the
continuation of a trend that has been operative for quite sometime now.
The foreign exchange assets of the central bank rose sharply, from $42.3
billion at the end of March 2001 to 54.1 billion at the end of March
2002, $75.4 billion at the end of March 2003 and $113 billion at the
end of March 2004. This implies that even after discounting for the
increase in reserves resulting from the appreciation of the dollar value
of the RBI's Sterling, Yen and Euro reserves, the foreign exchange assets
of the central bank were rising by around $980 million a month in 2001-02,
$1.4 billion a month in 2002-03 and $2.5 billion a month during 2003-04.
The process of reserve accumulation is the result of the pressure on
the central bank to purchase foreign currency in order to shore up demand
and dampen the effects on the rupee of excess supplies of foreign currency.
In India's liberalized foreign exchange markets, excess supply leads
to an appreciation of the rupee, which in turn undermines the competitiveness
of India's exports. Since improved export competitiveness and an increase
in exports is a leading objective of economic liberalization, the persistence
of a tendency towards rupee appreciation would imply that the reform
process is internally contradictory. Not surprisingly the RBI and the
government have been keen to dampen, if not stall, appreciation.
The Indian rupee's appreciation vis-à-vis the dollar began in
June 2002, when it had touched a low of more than Rs. 49 to the dollar.
More recently, the rupee has been rising vis-à-vis the Euro as
well over the last four months. During these periods of ascent, it has
appreciated by close to 12 per cent vis-à-vis the dollar in 22
months and by a significant 9 per cent vis-à-vis the Euro in
a short period of 4 months. Not surprisingly, exporters have begun to
get restive; since a loss of 10 per cent in the rupee price of their
exports can shave off margins on past fixed-price dollar/euro contracts
and make it difficult to win new orders.
The rise of the rupee is partly attributable to the depreciation of
the other currencies, especially the dollar against those of its competitors.
That this was true for some time is reflected in the fact that while
the rupee was appreciating against the dollar for close to two years,
it was depreciating vis-à-vis the euro for much of this period.
This is, however, only small cause for comfort, since most export contracts
are denominated in dollar terms. Moreover, in recent months, as noted
above, the rupee has been appreciating against the euro as well.
Since these were periods when the RBI was purchasing foreign currencies
and fattening its reserves, it should be clear that exchange rate management
through currency market intervention had been crucial in dampening the
rupee's appreciation vis-à-vis the dollar and relative stability
vis-à-vis the Euro. Unfortunately, the RBI's ability to persist
with this policy without eroding its ability to control domestic money
supply is increasingly under threat.
The task of managing the rupee is daunting because, when the central
bank increases its foreign currency assets to hold down the value of
the local currency, there would be a corresponding matching increase
in the liabilities of the central bank, amounting to the rupee resources
it releases within the domestic economy to acquire the foreign exchange
assets. If forced to continuously acquire such assets, the resulting
release of rupee resources would lead to a sharp increase in money supply,
undermining the monetary policy objectives of the central bank. Since
financial liberalization implies abjuring direct measures of intervention
to curb credit and money supply increases, the central bank has sought
to neutralize the effects of reserve accumulation on its asset position
by divesting itself of domestic securities through sale of government
securities it holds.
This process of ''sterilizing'' the effects of foreign capital inflows
through sale of government securities has, however, proceeded too far.
The volume of rupee securities (including treasury bills) held by the
RBI has fallen from Rs. 150,000 crore at the end of March 2001 to Rs.140,000
crore at the end of March 2002 and Rs. 115,000 crore at the end of March
2003, before collapsing to less than Rs.30,000 crore by the end of March
2004. The possibility of using its stock of government securities to
sterilize the effects of capital flows on money supply has almost been
exhausted.
It was possibly this factor which accounted for the reticence of the
central bank to hold back on currency purchases in recent weeks, resulting
in a faster appreciation of the rupee. Fortunately for the RBI, it was
helped on this front by the uncertainty created by the results of the
exit polls conducted midway through the Parliament elections. The week
ended April 30 witnessed a collapse in India's stock markets. On Wednesday,
April 27, the Sensex fell by 213 points, wiping clean an estimated Rs.
55,000 crore of paper ''wealth''. This was the largest single-day decline
in over three years. Over the rest of the week the markets moved further
down, indicating that ''Black Wednesday'' was possibly not just a stray
blip on the trading screen. With evidence that foreign institutional
investors who were earlier pumping foreign currency into India's markets
were holding back, the rupee too witnessed a reversal of the rise that
excess dollar supplies had been resulting in.
There is unanimity among ''analysts'' of the factor driving the downturn:
news from the exit polls – the most ''scientific'' of available predictions
– that the NDA is unlikely to win a majority in the elections, which
may throw up a hung Parliament. In the run up to the elections, India's
''upper crust'' – consisting of ''the markets'', the media and large
sections of the urban middle class - had convinced itself that the results
of the elections were a forgone conclusion: the NDA would form the government;
only the margin of victory was a matter for debate. The initial opinion
polls only confirmed this belief. It is therefore not surprising that
the results of the exit polls at the end of two rounds of voting came
as a shock, marginally reversing the rupee's decline.
While this provided the RBI some respite in its increasingly difficult
task of managing the rupee, the development raises a new spectre. If
just the possibility of a fractured election result could set off a
collapse in the market and a slide in the rupee, the developments that
led to India's strong foreign exchange reserve position seem to have
increased its vulnerability as well. Investor confidence seems easy
to shake and if shaken its effects could be dramatic.
What
is noteworthy is the quick response to the exit poll results of the
market, which declared its displeasure with actions that not only erode
the wealth of its own constituents but, through their impact on credit
and foreign exchange markets, threaten a crisis in India's liberalized
financial sector. Market developments over the week ended April 30th
cannot be explained by the stray action of a few unhappy and/or nervous
investors. The herd instinct, so typical of financial markets and especially
of foreign institutional investors, has resulted in concerted action
that threatens a sharp decline. And in India's markets, which are neither
wide nor deep, a small herd can make a big difference.
On
the surface, an early correction of the baseless expectations of a few
financial investors should not be cause for worry. Few can demonstrate
that India's till-quite-recently inactive financial markets drive the
economy. However, the problem is that the crises that such changed expectations
resulted in elsewhere in East Asia, Latin America, Eastern Europe and
Turkey show that they tend to damage the real economy as well. Moreover,
when the crisis of finance becomes a crisis of the real economy, its
burden falls disproportionately on the poor and the lower middle classes,
even though they do not participate in or often are not even conscious
of the workings of financial markets. Having invited foreign financial
investors into their economies, countries find that ignoring their sentiments
and/or closing the door on them when they retreat, involves painful
adjustments that the people, and therefore democratic governments, find
hard to face up to.
Thus, India seems to have a double problem on its balance of payments.
Net foreign exchange inflows are a problem because they threaten an
appreciation of the currency and a decline in exports. Foreign exchange
outflows are a problem because they seem to result from even non-economic
factors, and could cumulate into a crisis if they trigger a cycle of
unfulfilled expectations. The only redeeming feature is the high level
of India's reserves, which gives it space for manoeuvre.
The question is really the form these manoeuvres should take. Clearly
mere open market intervention to neutralize the effects of excess foreign
currency supply is inadequate. What needs to be looked at is the possibility
of managing net foreign currency flows themselves. An examination of
the balance of payments offers some pointers on what needs to be done
in this regard.
The pressure on the rupee leading to its appreciation, which is affecting
export competitiveness adversely, arises because India, which has recorded
a current account surplus since financial year 2001-02 (Chart 4), has
encouraged and attracted large inflows on its capital account. India's
current account surplus, we must note, is not a reflection of its strong
trade performance. Rather, as Chart 1 shows, it is because net inflows
under what is called the ''invisibles'' head of the current account
of the balance of payments have been more than adequate to finance a
large and recently rising merchandise trade deficit.
The principal sources of current account inflows have been buoyant remittance
flows, captured under the ''Transfers'' head, and inflows on account
of ''software services'' captured under the ''Miscellaneous Services''
head (Charts 2 and 3). That is, transfers made by Indian workers abroad,
either on short or long-term contracts and software service exports,
have helped overcome the adverse balance of payments consequences of
India's lack of competitiveness reflected in a large trade deficit.
Inflows on account of software services rose from $5.75 billion in 2000-01
to $6.88 billion in 2001-02, $8.86 billion in 2002-03 and $9.09 billion
over the first nine months of 2003-04, while private transfers (mainly
remittances) touched $15.2 billion in 2002-03 and $14.6 billion during
April-December 2003, after having fallen from $13.1 billion to $12.5
billion between 2000-01 and 2001-02. In an intensification of this trend,
during the first nine months of the recently ended financial year 2003-04,
net inflows on account of invisibles was, at $18.22 billion, well above
the $15 billion deficit on the trade account.
Even
while India's current account was relatively healthy on account of the
foreign exchange largesse of Indian workers abroad and the software
services boom, the country's liberalized capital markets have attracted
large inflows of capital amounting to a net sum of $10.57 billion in
2001-02, $12.11 billion in 2002-03 and a massive $17.31 billion during
the first nine months of 2003-04 (Chart 4). Expectations are that, because
of huge portfolio capital inflows during the last three months of 2003-04
encouraged by the government's privatization drive, net capital account
inflows during 2003-04 will be in excess of $20 billion.
There are two issues that arise in this context. The first relates to
the nature of the capital inflows during these years. The second relates
to the implications of these inflows for the value of the rupee under
India's liberalized exchange rate management system. Three kinds of
inflows have dominated the capital account (Chart 5). An early and important
source of inflow during the years of financial liberalization has been
in the form of NRI deposits in lucrative, repatriable foreign currency
accounts. On a net basis, such inflows accounted for $2.32 billion,
$2.75 billion, $2.98 billion and $3.5 billion respectively in 2000-01,
2000-02, 2002-03 and April-December 2003, respectively. They reflect
the attempt by richer non-residents to exploit arbitrage opportunities
offered by the higher (relative to international rates) interest rates
on repatriable, non-resident, foreign exchange accounts, to earn relatively
easy surpluses.
A
second important source of capital inflows has been portfolio capital
flows, reflecting investments by foreign bodies, especially foreign
institutional investors, in India's stock and debt markets, encouraged
more recently by the disinvestment of shares in profitable public sector
undertakings. On a net basis, such inflows had fallen from $2.8 billion
in 2000-01 to $2.0 billion in 2001-02 and just $979 million in 2002-03,
but rose sharply to $7.6 billion in the first nine months of 2003-04.
As compared with this, net foreign direct investment which rose from
$4.0 billion in 2000-01 to $6.1 billion in 2001-02 fell to 4.7 billion
in 2002-03 and $3.2 billion during April-December 2003.
The third important source of capital was a financial liberalization-induced
increase in the net liabilities of commercial banks (other than in the
form of NRI deposits), which rose from a negative $1.43 billion in 2000-01
to $2.63 billion in 2001-02, $5.15 billion in 2002-03 and $2.56 billion
during April-December 2003. This is possibly explained by the expansion
of the operations of international banks in the country.
In sum, capital inflows that create new capacities either in manufacturing
or in the infrastructural sectors have been limited. Much of the capital
inflow has consisted of financial investments that expect to earn higher
annual returns than available in international markets or obtain windfall
gains from the appreciation of the value of such investments, as has
recently been witnessed in India's stock markets.
Given the determination of the exchange rate of the rupee by supply
and demand conditions in the market, this large inflow of foreign capital
in the context of a current account surplus was bound to exert an upward
pressure on the rupee. When inflows contribute to an appreciation of
the rupee, foreign investors also gain from the larger pay off in foreign
currency that any given return in rupees involves. This tends to increase
the volume of inflows. The real losers are exporters, on the one hand,
who find that the foreign exchange prices of their products are rising,
eroding their competitiveness, and domestic producers, on the other,
who find that the prices of competing imports are falling or rising
less that their own costs of production.
If the government wants to manage these capital inflows, it needs to
control inflows on account of NRI deposits, portfolio flows and banking,
all of which are the results of excessive financial liberalization,
do not contribute to enhancing productive investment, offer extremely
high returns that imply a net foreign exchange loss to the country when
matched by the low returns obtained on accumulated reserves, and are
extremely footloose in character. India's current account position is
such that it does not need large capital inflows for a comfortable balance
of payments. In particular, it does not need inflows that increase financial
vulnerability without contributing to any increase in productive investment
or exports. By doing away with the differential in interest rates offered
on non-resident external accounts and international interest rates,
the central bank has taken the first step forward. It must now go further.