|
|
|
|
Revisiting
Capital Flows* |
|
May
4th 2011, C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh |
|
A
striking feature of the recent global financial crisis
and its aftermath is the behaviour of private international
capital flows, especially to emerging markets. Prior
to the crisis, in the years after 2003, a number of
analysts had noted that the world was witnessing a
surge in capital flows to emerging markets. These
flows, relative to GDP, were comparable in magnitude
to levels recorded in the period immediately preceding
the financial crisis in Southeast Asia in 1997. They
were also focused on a few developing countries, which
were facing difficulties managing these flows so as
to stabilise exchange rates and retain control over
monetary policy. They also included a significant
volume of debt-creating flows, besides other forms
of portfolio flows.
Interestingly, these developments did not, as in 1997,
lead up to widespread financial and currency crisis
originating in emerging markets, as happened in 1997.
However, the risks involved in attracting these kinds
of flows were reflected in the way the financial crisis
of 2008 in the developed countries affected emerging
markets. Financial firms from the developed world,
incurring huge losses during the crisis in their countries
of origin, chose to book profits and exit from the
emerging markets, in order to cover losses and/or
meet commitments at home. In the event, the crisis
led to a transition from a situation of large inflows
to emerging markets to one of large outflows, reducing
reserves, adversely affecting currency values and
creating in some contexts a liquidity crunch.
Given the legacy of inflows and the consequent reserve
accumulation, this, however, was to be expected. What
has been surprising is the speed with which this scenario
once again transformed itself, with developing countries
very quickly finding themselves the target of capital
inflows of magnitudes that are quickly approaching
those observed during the capital surge. As the IMF
noted in the latest (April 2011) edition of its World
Economic Outlook: ''For many EMEs, net flows in the
first three quarters of 2010 had already outstripped
the averages reached during 2004–07,'' though they
were still below their pre-crisis highs.
One implication of the quick restoration of the capital
inflow surge is the fact that, in the medium-term,
net capital inflows into developing countries in general,
and emerging markets in particular, has become much
more volatile. As Chart 1 shows, net capital flows
which were small though the 1980s, rose significantly
during 1991-96, only to decline after the 1997 crisis
to touch close to early-1990s levels by the end of
the decade. But the amplitude of these fluctuations
in capital inflows was small when compared with what
has followed since, with the surge between 2002 and
2007 being substantially greater, the collapse in
2008 much sharper and the recovery in 2010 much quicker
and stronger.
Chart
1 >> Click
to Enlarge
When
we examine the composition of flows we find that volatility
is substantial in two kinds of capital flows: ''private
portfolio flows'' and ''other private'' flows, with
the latter including debt (Chart 2). There has been
much less volatility in the case of direct investment
flows. However, in recent years the size of non-direct
investment flows has been substantial enough to provide
much cause for concern. Further, besides the fact that
direct investment flows are differentially distributed
across countries (with China taking a large share),
the definition of direct investment is such that the
figure includes a large chunk of portfolio flows. The
magnitude of the problem is, therefore, still large.
Does this increase in volatility during the decade of
the 2000s speak of changes in the factors driving and
motivating capital flows to emerging markets? The IMF
in its World Economic Outlook does seem to think so,
though the argument is not formulated explicitly. In
its analysis of long-term trends in capital flows the
IMF does link the volatility in flows to the role of
monetary conditions (and by implication monetary policy)
in the developed countries, especially the US, in influencing
those flows.
As the WEO puts it, ''Historically, net flows to EMEs
have tended to be higher under low global interest rates,
(and) low global risk aversion,'' though this assessment
is tempered with references to the importance of domestic
factors. Shorn of jargon, there appears to be two arguments
being advanced here. The first is that capital flows
to emerging markets are largely influenced by factors
from the supply-side, facilitated no doubt by easy entry
conditions into these economies resulting from financial
liberalisation. The second is that easy monetary policies
in the developed countries has encouraged and driven
capital flows to developing countries. This is because
easy and larger access to liquidity encourages investment
abroad, while lower interest rates promote the ''carry-trade'',
where investors borrow in dollars to invest in emerging
markets and earn higher financial returns, based on
the expectation that exchange rate changes would not
reduce or neutralise the differential in returns. Needless
to say, when monetary policy in the developed countries
is tightened, the differential falls and capital flows
can slow down and even reverse themselves.
Chart
2 >> Click
to Enlarge
The evidence clearly supports such a view. The period
of the capital surge prior to 2007 was one where the
Federal Reserve in the US, for example, adopted an easy
money policy, involving large infusion of liquidity
and low interest rates. While this was aimed at spurring
credit-financed domestic demand, especially for housing,
so as to sustain growth, it also encouraged financial
firms to invest in lucrative markets abroad. Flows reversed
themselves when the losses and the uncertainty resulting
from the sub-prime crisis and its aftermath resulted
in a credit crunch. Finally, flows resumed and rose
sharply when the US government responded to the crisis
with huge infusions of cheap liquidity into the system,
aimed at relaxing the liquidity crunch. A substantial
part of the so-called stimulus consisted of periodic
resort to ''quantitative easing'' or the loosening of
monetary controls.
This close link between monetary policy in the developed
countries and capital flows to emerging markets is of
particular significance because, with the turn to fiscal
conservatism, the monetary lever has become the principal
instrument for macroeconomic management. Since that
lever can be moved in either direction (monetary easing
or stringency), net flows can move either into or out
of emerging markets. As a corollary, the consequence
of monetary policy being in ascendance is a high degree
of volatility and lowered persistence of capital inflows
to these countries.
From the point of view of developing countries the implications
are indeed grave. When global conditions are favourable
for an inflow of capital to the developing countries,
these countries experience a capital surge. This creates
problems for the simultaneous management of the exchange
rate and monetary policy in these countries, and leads
to the costly accumulation of excess of foreign exchange
reserves. Costly because the return earned from investing
accumulated reserves is a fraction of that earned by
investors who bring this capital to the developing economy.
Moreover, when global conditions turn unfavourable for
capital flows, capital flows out, reserves are quickly
depleted and there is much uncertainty in currency and
financial markets.
The problem is particularly acute for countries that
are more integrated with US financial markets, since
dependence on the monetary level is far greater in that
country, partly because of the advantages derived from
the dollar being the world's reserve currency. The IMF's
WEO, therefore, predicts: ''economies with greater direct
financial exposure to the United States will experience
greater additional declines in net flows because of
U.S. monetary tightening, compared with economies with
lesser U.S. financial exposure.'' This tallies with
the evidence. Overall, ''event studies demonstrate an
inverted V-shaped pattern of net capital flows to EMEs
around events outside the policymakers' control, underscoring
the fickle nature of capital flows from the perspective
of the recipient economy.''
This increase in externally driven vulnerability explains
the IMF's recent rethink on the use of capital controls
by developing countries. Having strongly dissuaded countries
from opting for such controls in the past, the IMF now
seems to have veered around to the view that they may
not be all bad. However, its endorsement of such measures
has been grudging and partial. In a report prepared
in the run up to this year's spring meetings of the
Fund and the World Bank, the IMF makes a case for what
it terms capital flow management measures, but recommends
them as a last resort and as temporary measures, to
be adopted only when a country has accumulated sufficient
reserves and experienced currency appreciation, despite
having experimented with interest rate policies. This
may be too little, too late. But, fortunately, many
developing countries have gone much further. Only a
few like India, which is also the target of a capital
surge, seem still ideologically disinclined.
*
This article was originally published in The Businessline,
3 May, 2011.
|
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|