Even though agriculture has been the sector least affected by the
reforming zeal that overcame successive government's since 1991,
substantial headway has been made in this sector as well. The Finance
Ministry's Economic Survey 1993-94 summarised the case for and the extent
of liberalisation of agricutural trade as follows: "Indian farm products
are characterised by extremely low import content compared to non-farm
exportables. Exchange rate convertibility on the trade account has
therefore enabled many farm-based products to become internationally
competitive. Rice, wheat, cotton, fruits and vegetables and flowers are
some of the non-traditional exportables. Some of the measures initiated
recently to accelerate the growth of agricultural exports are : (i)
minimum export price (MEP) on basmati rice, pepper, guargum, orchids and
meat of sheep, goat and buffalo has been removed; (ii) exports of milk
products have been decanalised; (iii) permission has been granted to
freely export superfine non-basmati rice subject to an MEP which has been
reduced to $200 per tonne; (iv) exports of mustard seeds and rapeseds have
been allowed against quota; (v) exports of wheat products have been
decontrolled and exports of high value durum wheat and of non-FAQ jowar
permitted subject to ceiling; and (vi) cession of sugar exports has been
waived and cess on pepper exports suspended." Since then further advances
with regard to liberalisation have been made, culminating in the sweeping
liberalisation implicit in the Export-Import Policy announced in April
this year.
Exports of agricultural products initially appeared to respond to these
moves, rising from $3136 million in 1992/93 to $4023 million in 1993/94,
$4227 million in 1994/95, $6119 million in 1995/96 and $6868 million in
1996/97. This initial post-reform buoyancy in exports led to considerable
optimism about the likely effect of the Uruguay Round agreement on India's
agricultural sector. The stipulations that developed countries should
reduce production subsidies paid to their farmers and roll-back non-tariff
barriers restricting agricultural trade were expected to substantially
benefit India, because of the comparative advantage she had in the area.
It is the persistence of that optimism which underlies the widespread
perception that it would be to India's advantage if there are further
advances made with regard to liberalisation of agricultural trade in the
proposed new Round of trade negotiations.
Such optimism notwithstanding, there are reasons to be less sanguine about
India's agricultural-export potential. To start with, more recently
agro-product exports seem to be slipping, having touched $6633 million in
1997/98 and $5994 million in 1998/99, compared to the peak of $6868
million in 1996/97. Further there are signs that the price advantages that
India
had in the world markets for some commodities like rice and cotton are
diminishing. This is significant because these were the two commodities
which were expected garner major gains from liberalisation. In an early
analysis of the impact of trade liberalisation on agriculture, Deepak
Nayyar and Abhijit Sen argued as follows: "Clearly, as with any
liberalisation, there will be gainers and losers from agricultural trade
in India.
The most obvious way of looking at this is to say that the gainers would
be the producers of crops such as rice and cotton which are currently
priced below world prices and consumers of goods such as sugar and
oilseeds which are currently priced above world prices." (See
"International Trade and the Agricultural Sector" in G.S. Bhalla (ed.),
Economic Liberalisation and Agriculture 1994). While developments in the
rice and cotton trade are questioning this judgement, in areas like
oilseeds and vegetable oils, where India was not internationally
competitive, but moving towards a high degree of self-sufficiency on the
basis of domestic production aided by protection, liberalisation is having
rather devastating consequences.
The immediate post-reform buoyancy in agricultural
exports was in large measure due to a sharp increase in the export of
rice. As Chart 1 shows, rice exports which were mildly buoyant during
1992-94, registered a huge jump in 1995-96, with exports rising five-fold
by more than four million tonnes in that one year. Almost all of that
increase was a result of the export of non-basmati varieties which,
because of export restrictions in earlier years, did not feature as a
major export from India . As Chart 3 shows the buoyancy in rice exports
was almost wholly responsible for the buoyancy in foodgrains exports.
However, the rice export boom of 1995-96 proved to be exceptional. It was
followed by a sharp fall over the next two years. Though there are signs
of a second revival in 1998-99, with rice exports estimated at 4.7 million
tonnes as compared with the 1995-96 peak of close to 5 million tonnes,
there are reasons to believe that such buoyancy may not be sustained.
Consider for example trends in the domestic and export prices (f.o.b.)
of rice . The period since 1992-93 has on average been characterised by a
widening of the price differentials between domestic and exports sales. As
a result, when the government permitted export of non-basmati varieties,
the higher price to be garnered from the export market encouraged a
diversification of supplies to the world market, strengthening the view
that India had substantial comparative advantages in rice production.
However, in absolute terms international prices have been falling during
the later part of this period. According to the Commission for
Agricultural Costs and Prices, the unit value realised for export of
non-basmati rice declined from Rs. 9677 ($272.6) per tonne in 1996-97, to
Rs. 9603 ($258.4) in 1997-98 and further to Rs. 9429 ($221.9) in 1998-99
(April-Nov.). These prices were in fact less than the economic cost of
providing rice incurred by the FCI and only about 10-20 per cent higher
than the levy prices in the many states. This suggests that so long as the
rate of increase in support prices is higher than any depreciation in the
value of the rupee, the price advantage that Indian rice exporters enjoy
could be eroded.
Rice has dominated
foodgrain exports because of the restrictions that apply on exports of
wheat and coarse grains. While the export of rice is permitted freely,
wheat and coarse grain exports require a licence and are subject to
quantitative restrictions. The ceiling for exports of these commodities
are determined based on domestic availability and were, for example, set
at one lakh tonnes each in 1998-99. So long as these ceilings remain in
place, export trends do not reflect
India's
competitive advantage in these areas, but relative price comparisons
suggest that in the case of wheat , the advantages that prevailed during
the period 1993-94 to 1995-96 have since been lost.
Another crop which was considered a major agricultural
exportable from India is raw cotton. Hitherto, cotton exports have been
regulated under a policy which provided for exports of about 5 lakh bales
(of 170 kg each) a year. In practice, export volumes are influenced by
domestic supply conditions and have tended to vary substantially. During
the 1990s, exports touched a peak of 16.8 lakh bales in cotton year
1996-97 , when production was also at a record high of 178 lakh bales.
What is noteworthy however is the buoyancy in cotton imports in recent
seasons, with imports rising from a low of 0.3 lakh bales in 1996-97 to 4
lakh bales in 19987-98 and a projected record level of 6.5 lakh bales and
an estimated actual export of around 5 lakh bales in 1998-99.
Interestingly, as Chart 8 shows, in two of these three years
(1997-98 and 1998-99) the price differential between comparable Indian and
foreign varieties of cotton have (in the one case cited) virtually
disappeared. In all previous years during the 1990s, international prices
have consistently ruled higher than domestic prices. The erosion of the
price differential is more due to the decline in international prices
rather than any significant rise in domestic prices, suggesting that
international price trends in the case of this commodity, considered a
potential foreign exchange earner for India, have moved in directions
which have undermined
India's
competitive advantage.
More recent evidence indicates that the problem is unlikely to
disappear. It is estimated that imports would be even higher in the
current cotton year, despite the fact that the Cotton Advisory Board has
projected output at 175 lakh bales in 1999-2000, as compared with 163.5
lakh bales in the previous year. Further, initial stocks this year are
placed at 49 lakh bales as compared with 36.5 lakh bales in 1998-99. High
production and larger initial stocks suggest that cotton prices would rule
much lower during the coming cotton season. In fact, reports from
different parts of the country indicate that cotton prices have fallen by
10-20 per cent during November. Yet, cotton imports during the current
season have been projected at 8 lakh bales, compared with 5 lakh bales in
the previous year, because imported cotton enjoys both price and quality
advantages. The problem is that with international prices easing as well,
it is expected that the price parity between domestic and imported cotton
is unlikely to be disturbed during the year, resulting in a persistence of
the import surge.
All in all, therefore, recent trends do suggest caution when claiming that
India would benefit substantially from agricultural trade liberalisation.
The experience with two of the commodities considered front runners in
terms of competitive advantage, namely rice and raw cotton, reflects price
and trade trends which suggest that such advantage is tenuous to say the
least.
While foreign exchange gains from agricultural trade
liberalisation are thus uncertain, there are signs that losses in terms of
additional post-liberalisation outflows on account of imports can be
significant. While imports of cereals are in general canalised through the
Food Corporation of India, coarse and common varieties of rice and rice
with 50 per cent broken content are allowed to be imported freely. All
cereal imports are not subject to any duty. Chart 4 shows that
during the 1980s, foodgrain imports were extremely volatile, rising
sharply in the wake of bad or indifferent harvests of the kind seen in
1979-80, 1982-83, and 1987-88. Thus import movements were clearly related
to domestic production trends. While this remained partly true in the
1990s, there has been a tendency for imports to rise after 1995-96 and
remain at moderately high levels. From a low level of just 8.3 thousand
tonnes in 1995-96, cereal imports rose to 6.1 lakh tonnes in 1996-97, 14.9
lakh tonnes in 1997-98 and 11.5 lakh tonnes in the first eight months of
1998-99. Almost all of these imports were of wheat, since there were
virtually no imports of rice during 1996-97 and
1998-99.
In the food products area, the real impact of liberalisation has occurred
in vegetable oils. Though oilseeds imports are permitted, imports take the
form of edible oils, which are freely importable except for coconut oil,
RBD palm oil, RBD palm stearine and palm kernel oil, which till April 1,
1999 were canalised imports. As Chart 5 shows, imports of edible oils rose
sharply from 103,000 tonnes in 1992-93 to 347,000 tonnes in 1994-95, 1.06
million tonnes in 1995-96 and 1.42 million tonnes in 1996-97. Though
imports dipped slightly to 1.14 million tonnes in 1997-98, they rose
sharply again and stood at 1.71 million tonnes during the first eight
months of 1998-99.
These imports occurred despite a continuous rise in
the unit value of edible oil imports from Rs. 6.2 per kg. in 1990-91 to
Rs. 30.13 per kg. in 1998-99. While a part of this increase in the unit
vale of exports may be on account of a shift to higher value oils in the
import basket, the data suggest that a combination of taste changes and
domestic price trends have worked against the domestic oilseeds and
vegetable oil producers. In one instance, viz. soyabean oil, where,
according to one estimate, earlier price relatives where in favour of the
domestic trade once again a rise in domestic prices has eroded the price
differential, rendering imports an attractive option.
The situation appears
to be deteriorating rapidly. According to the Solvent Extractors'
Association of India, the import of vegetable oils during the oil year
1998-99 stood at 4.39 million tonnes, which was more than double the
figure of 2.08 million tonnes in the previous year. Quoting Oil World
weekly, they argue that imports during 1999-2000 could be as high as 4.7
to 4.9 million tonnes. Refined palmolein reportedly accounts for around 60
per cent of these exports.
Overall India's weakening competitive edge in recent times is essentially
the result of a sharp decline in international prices. The international
prices of agricultural commodities, which registered a sharp rise during
1992-96, have recorded an even sharper fall since then, taking them to a
decadal low. According to the food and agricultural raw materials price
indices of the International Monetary Fund, prices fell by 13 and 16 per
cent in 1998, after similar declines in the previous year. Prices are
projected to fall further in 1999.
It is not just the fall in prices that is a matter of concern, but the
inter-commodity variations in impact of imports on domestic prices. With
pulses and edible oil imports being placed under OGL as part of
liberalisation, the real prices of these commodities have either declined
or remained stagnant. On the other hand, there are crops which have seen
increase in prices in real terms during these years. This obviously
results in a shift of acreage away from certain crops to others, making
India
increasingly import dependent in some areas. At one level, this is a
matter of concern from the point of view of food security, since it is
likely that prices would remain high for various commercial crops that
have a large international demand while remaining low for a range of food
crops. But that is not all. Trade liberalisation could lead to substantial
instability. Since India's large demand for particular commodities is
likely to affect international prices substantially, a shift out of one
crop in domestic production and in its favour in imports could trigger
prices increases that induce acreage shift reversals. Such price and
output instability is hardly the recipe for building competitive
capabilities, which is the ostensible aim of liberalisation.
These possibilities that trade liberalisation could
adversely affect agriculture need to be viewed in the light of evidence
which suggests that the overall benefits to agriculture from
liberalisation have thus far been limited. One fall out of overall trade
liberalisation was to be a shift in the terms of trade between agriculture
and manufacturing in favour of agriculture, as a result of a fall in
manufactured goods prices and a rise in agricultural prices. However, as
Chart 12 shows, while the terms of trade have been in favour of
agriculture during the 1990s, the gains in those terms were registered
during the 1980s and not the 1990s. During the 1990s, the terms have trade
have fluctuated around a more or less stagnant trend, and have equalled
the 1991-92 level only in one other year. And if our analysis of the
likely price consequences of liberalisation materialise, there is a
possibility of a decline in those terms in the years to come.
In sum, liberalisation of trade, even to the extent that it
had proceeded before the Exim policy announced in April this year, has not
delivered the promise of benefits to agriculture that it held out. On the
other hand, there are signs that the consequences for agriculture could
prove adverse in future. The case for caution while advocating further
liberalisation of agricultural trade either at home or at the WTO is
therefore obvious.
|