Estimates
made by the National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector
(NCEUS) provide a much clearer picture of employment in the organized
industrial sector than available hitherto. They make the much needed
distinction between “employment in the organized sector” (defined to
include all enterprises employing ten or more workers with power or
20 or more workers without power and therefore seen as subject to the
Factories Act) and “organized employment”, or employment that has associated
with it a minimum of employment, work and social security. If organized
employment is taken to consist of all employment in units that fall
under the formal sector definition, then such employment is estimated
to have risen from 54.1 million to 62.6 million between 1999-2000 and
2004-05. However, if the definition is restricted to “organized workers”
in the organized sector, then “formal” employment in the organized sector
had fallen marginally from 33.7 million in 1999-00 to 33.4 million in
2004-05. This compares with total employment of 361.7 million and 422.6
million respectively on these two dates. With manufacturing employment
having remained near-stagnant at 12.1 and 12.9 million respectively
during these two years, we can safely conclude that the manufacturing
sector’s contribution to organized employment is not just small relative
to the total, but must have stagnated or declined.
It is indeed true that this was expected to some extent given the fact
that more than 60 per cent of the increment in GDP in the years after
1991 have come from the services sector, and the manufacturing sector’s
share has declined. However, there have been periods when manufacturing
production has been buoyant and growth creditable. One such period is
that after 2001-02, which, if everything else remained the same, should
have contributed to an increase in employment in organized manufacturing
between 1993-94 or 1999-2000 and 2004-05.
If this has not happened, it must be because average labour productivity
in manufacturing has grown so fast that the effects of the higher rate
of increase in output on employment growth would have been more than
neutralized. This indeed appears to be the case. According to estimates
quoted in the Planning Commission’s Eleventh Plan Document, GDP per
worker in manufacturing which grew at 2.29 per cent per annum during
1983 to 1993-94 accelerated to 3.31 per cent between 1993-94 and 2004-05.
It is to be expected that this acceleration would have been sharper
in the case of organized manufacturing, because of the effects of reform.
Prabhat Patnaik argues that the combination of high output growth and
low employment growth is a feature characterising many developing countries
during the years when they opened their economies to trade and investment.
This is because (i) with tastes and preferences of the elite in developing
countries being influenced by the “demonstration effect” of lifestyles
in the developed countries, new products and processes introduced in
the latter very quickly find their way to the developing countries when
their economies are opened, and (ii) technological progress in the form
of new products and processes in the developed countries is inevitably
associated with an increase in labour productivity, so that increased
imports of technology imply increased productivity. Hence after trade
liberalisation, labour productivity growth in developing countries is
exogenously driven and tends to be higher than prior to trade liberalisation,
leading to a growing divergence between output and employment growth.
This tendency is exaggerated by the demand-side effects of financial
liberalization. One consequence of financial liberalisation and the
excess liquidity in the system created by the inflow of foreign capital,
has been the growing importance of credit provided to individuals for
specific purposes such as purchases of housing property, consumer durables
and automobiles of various kinds. Credit has had an important role to
play in the expansion of the market for manufactures during the years
of reform: through a boom in housing and consumer credit.
An important implication of debt-financed manufacturing demand is that
it is inevitably concentrated in the first instance in a narrow range
of commodities that are the targets of personal finance. Commodities
whose demand is expanded with credit finance vary from construction
materials to automobiles and consumer durables. These commodities, which
must serve as the collateral for the debt that finances their purchase,
must be in the nature of durables and are more-often than not the products
of metal- and chemical-based industries and therefore tend to be more
capital intensive and are characterised by higher labour productivity.
This factor, together with the industrial “restructuring” associated
with liberalisation, has resulted in a sharp and persistent increase
in labour productivity (as measured by the net value added at constant
prices generated per worker) in the organised manufacturing sector during
the years of liberalisation. As Chart 1 shows, labour productivity tripled
during 1981-82 and 1996-97, stagnated and even slightly declined during
the years of the industrial slowdown that set in thereafter, and has
once again been rising sharply in the early years of this decade.
There
are two factors that would have contributed to this sharp increase in
labour productivity. First, there has been an increase in capital-intensity
and labour productivity in individual industries. And, secondly, a faster
rate of increase in demand and production of capital intensive commodities
have resulted in an increase in the share of capital-intensive production
in the total. The shift in the pattern of demand results partly from
the role of credit-financed consumption noted above and partly from
the increases in income inequality that are associated with more liberalized
and open economic regimes.
How important have such changes in demand been in the Indian context?
Consider Charts 2 and 3, which give the distribution of the trend rates
of growth of the real value of output and net value added by 3-digit
industry groups in the registered manufacturing sector for the period
1993-94 to 2003-04. It should be clear that there is wide variation
in growth performance. A few sectors recorded remarkably high rates
of growth, though data problems may be exaggerating figures at the two
tails.
Now consider
Table 1, which seeks to relate the ranks of individual three-digit industries
in terms of the rates of growth of net valued added with their ranks
in terms of Average productivity at the beginning of the period, Productivity
growth between 1993-94 and 2003-04 and Average capital intensity at
the end of the period (Capital intensity has been calculated using capital
estimates based on the perpetual inventory accumulation method.)
Table 1: Growth, Productivity
and Capital Intensity
Rank Correlation Coefficient of Rate of Growth
of
Net Value Added with |
Average Productivity 1993-94 to 1995-96 |
0.20 |
Productivity Growth 1993-94 to 2003-04 |
0.48 |
Average Capital-Labour Ratio 1993-94 to 1995-96 |
0.25 |
Table 2: Top 25
industrial categories in terms of rate of growth of labour productivity
Industry |
Code |
RoG |
Manufacture of railway and tramway locomotives
and rolling stock |
352 |
76.6 |
Manufacture of coke oven products |
231 |
48.3 |
Manufacture of watches and clocks |
333 |
41.2 |
Dressing and dyeing of fur; manufacture of articles
of fur |
182 |
21.7 |
Manufacture of television and radio transmitters
and apparatus for line telephony and line telegraphy |
322 |
21.4 |
Manufacture of glass and glass products |
261 |
20.9 |
Publishing |
221 |
17.3 |
Manufacture of motor vehicles |
341 |
15.1 |
Manufacture of domestic appliances, n.e.c. |
293 |
13.3 |
Manufacture of other electrical equipment n.e.c. |
319 |
13.0 |
Manufacture of structural metal products, tanks,
reservoirs and steam generators |
281 |
8.8 |
Manufacture of non-metallic mineral products n.e.c. |
269 |
6.8 |
Manufacture of refined petroleum products |
232 |
6.4 |
Manufacture of electric motors, generators and
transformers |
311 |
6.4 |
Manufacture of office, accounting and computing
machinery |
300 |
6.1 |
Manufacture of rubber products |
251 |
6.0 |
Manufacture of tobacco products |
160 |
5.4 |
Spinning, weaving and finishing of textiles |
171 |
4.6 |
Saw milling and planing of wood |
201 |
4.3 |
Manufacture of paper and paper product |
210 |
4.2 |
Manufacture of television and radio receivers,
sound or video recording or reproducing apparatus, and associated
goods |
323 |
4.0 |
Manufacture of accumulators, primary cells and
primary batteries |
314 |
4.0 |
Manufacture of dairy products |
152 |
3.5 |
Manufacture of man-made fibers |
243 |
3.4 |
Production, processing and preservation of meat,
fish, fruit vegetables, oils and fats |
151 |
3.1 |
The figures do point to a significant, even if not overwhelmingly strong,
relationship between value added growth on the one hand and productivity
growth on the other, and a reasonable association between the output/value
added variables and average productivity and average capital intensity.
Thus the faster growing sectors substantially include those that are
characterised by higher rates of growth of productivity and higher capital
intensity.
Table 2 provides information on the top 25 3-digit sectors in terms
of trend rates of increase in labour productivity among those for which
data is available. It should be clear that they cover all of the sectors
associated with the credit-financed and inequality-driven household
demand boom, suggesting that the pattern of growth associated with the
more open and liberalised regime of the 1990s has been significantly
responsible for the extremely poor showing in terms of employment growth
of an otherwise buoyant organized manufacturing sector.
|