The
discussion on the direction that financial regulation should take in
Asia inevitably turns to the diversity in regulation across countries
in its search for an appropriate combination of policies and measures.
The presumption here is that the rich diversity in the region offers
a menu from which a combination of institutions and instruments and
a corresponding regulatory framework can be put together. The case for
focusing on Asian policy has been strengthened by the resilience displayed
by Asian countries during the global financial crisis of 2007-08 and
after, despite their substantial integration with the global financial
system.
While there is a case for such an effort to learn from diversity, there
is also much evidence that monetary, fiscal and financial policies and
the associated macroeconomic scenario have been converging across Asian
countries since the onset of financial liberalisation and more so since
the Southeast Asian financial crisis of 1997. The ostensible role of
the 1997 crisis in influencing macroeconomic policy in these countries
has been much discussed after the global crisis. The 1997 experience,
it is argued, persuaded these countries to maintain a high volume of
foreign exchange reserves to deal with any volatility in cross-border
capital flows and excessive fluctuations in their currencies, leading
to a situation of capital flows from South to North, rather than North
to South as under the Bretton Woods system.
Among the many commonalities in the evolution of financial structures
in the region, there are a few that are particularly striking. The first
is, of course, the evidence of the growing integration of these economies
with the international financial system, which is reflected in a rising
ratio of net capital flows to GDP in almost all of these countries after
2003 and an increase in foreign bank claims on these countries in recent
years (Table 1). This is because, even while reserves accumulate, these
countries continue with open door policies that encourage cross-border
inflows of capital. The resulting outcome is relevant not merely because
it amounts to a reversal of the trend seen in the immediate post-1997
years, when as a result of the crisis the access of many countries to
foreign finance appeared to be falling. Clearly, countries now are able
to attract capital and are also unable to avoid or are willing to address
the dangers (in the form of balance of payments and/or currency crises)
of dependence on volatile cross-border flows.
From a policy point of view, the increase in the presence of foreign
capital has necessitated changes in the regulatory framework governing
finance in these countries. Governments in the region have adopted more
liberal rules with regard to the functioning of different kinds of markets
and institutions, provided greater space for new instruments such as
derivatives, and shown a willingness to shift to globally accepted rules
for regulation. One consequence has been a rapid shift to a Basel-type
regulatory framework for the banking system. In fact, countries in the
region are on average more eager to move on to Basel III than seems
to be the case even in the developed countries where the crisis that
forced the transition from Basel II to III occurred. The message seems
to be that if countries choose to adopt a macroeconomic policy framework
that emphasises the need to attract large volumes of foreign capital,
reform of the regulatory structure governing finance in a common, globally
dictated direction seems to be a prerequisite.
Table
1: International bank claims, consolidated
(Bn USD) |
|
Europe
|
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
44.3 |
90.0 |
98.7 |
261.0 |
Hong
Kong |
192.6 |
223.8 |
240.5 |
359.9 |
Indonesia |
12.6 |
19.5 |
22.7 |
36.1 |
India |
49.0 |
78.6 |
112.1 |
150.6 |
South
Korea |
120.7 |
165.5 |
159.5 |
161.4 |
Malaysia |
32.0 |
43.7 |
39.9 |
57.0 |
Singapore |
70.6 |
101.0 |
120.3 |
179.8 |
Thailand |
11.5 |
17.5 |
15.5 |
21.8 |
|
Japan
|
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
13.1 |
18.6 |
24.3 |
52.9 |
Hong
Kong |
19.2 |
23.9 |
28.6 |
50.8 |
Indonesia |
3.8 |
6.0 |
7.2 |
15.5 |
India |
5.9 |
8.4 |
11.7 |
25.2 |
South
Korea |
15.7 |
21.6 |
25.6 |
48.0 |
Malaysia |
5.8 |
6.3 |
9.1 |
13.7 |
Singapore |
11.8 |
16.9 |
26.0 |
40.8 |
Thailand |
9.8 |
12.6 |
14.5 |
35.1 |
|
US |
|
2005-Q4 |
2007-Q1 |
2009-Q1 |
2012-Q1 |
China |
9.8 |
21.7 |
51.6 |
76.9 |
Hong
Kong |
22.6 |
21.3 |
29.2 |
47.6 |
Indonesia |
2.8 |
4.9 |
5.9 |
12.7 |
India |
20.5 |
36.4 |
40.5 |
72.0 |
South
Korea |
54.6 |
71.5 |
72.4 |
94.7 |
Malaysia |
9.9 |
13.1 |
13.1 |
20.2 |
Singapore |
20.5 |
24.8 |
30.6 |
64.0 |
Thailand |
3.5 |
6.1 |
6.6 |
12.3 |
A
second element of commonality in these countries appears to be a growth
process associated with a large expansion of bank credit. Bank credit
growth has overshot GDP growth in almost all countries, resulting in a
sharp increase in the bank credit to GDP ratio (Chart 1). As is well known,
banks, given their dependence on deposits for their capital, would prefer
to avoid exposure to illiquid assets with lower resale value such as industrial
capital equipment, because it would expose them to the risks associated
with liquidity mismatches. The net result has been a substantial increase
in credit to the household sector or in retail credit/personal loans for
housing, for purchases of automobiles and durables and for consumption.
According to estimates relating to the middle of the last decade: ''Of
the domestic credit that banks have extended to private borrowers, a growing
share has gone to consumers. In 2004, consumer lending accounted for 53
per cent of total bank lending in Malaysia, 49 per cent in Korea, 30 per
cent in Indonesia, 17 per cent in Thailand, 15 per cent in China, and
10 per cent in the Philippines.'' Even in countries where the estimates
suggest that retail lending is low, such as China and Thailand, this is
because banks that do not lend directly to the household sector often
do so indirectly. They provide credit to a second tier of intermediaries,
often in the informal financial sector, which in turn lend to households.
While a large proportion of these loans is for housing, other loans such
as for purchases of automobiles or to finance credit-card receivables
have also increased considerably. The focus seems to be on lending short
term or against assets considered more liquid.
The third common feature in the evolution of Asian financial structures
is the kind of financial diversification visible in these economies.
Given the huge increase in banks' claims on other sectors of the economy,
the financial transformation of Asia has not been accompanied by a reduction
in the importance of banks in the financial sector. Rather banks still
account for a substantial share of assets resting in the financial sector.
Yet the evidence of a growing role for stock and bond markets and insurance
companies, mutual funds and pension funds is overwhelming. But the nature
of this presence needs examination.
Consider, to start with, the stock markets in these countries. An index
like the ratio of market capitalization to GDP (Chart 2), to a much
greater extent than the number of listed companies or the volume of
trading, points to a huge increase in the size of these markets. However,
much of this is a result of the inflation in stock prices that has resulted
from trading in the secondary market. The IPO market (or the role of
the stock market as a source of capital to finance corporate investment)
is still limited and highly volatile in terms of volumes mobilised.
Asset price inflation occurs partly because of the inflow of foreign
capital and domestic surpluses into the secondary market which is both
narrow (in terms of the number of companies whose shares are listed
and actively traded) and shallow (in terms of the number of shares of
these companies available for trading after taking account of the holdings
of promoters and long-term investors). In sum, though the stock market
seems present and growing in size and visibility, it is as yet not an
important agent from the point of view of making finance a supply-side
spur to corporate investment.
Interestingly, the development of the bond market too remains limited
and highly uneven across the region (Table 2). It is only in South Korea
that the corporate local currency bond market exceeds the government
bond market in size. Moreover, even where bond markets are developed,
government securities seem to account for a significant share of all
securities issued in the domestic market. There are differences in the
relative shares of the corporate bond market in the incremental growth
of these markets; but just as banking dominates the financial sector,
government securities still dominate bond markets in most contexts.
This is of significance given the trend towards reining in government
borrowing not just from central banks but also from the open market.
Unless counterbalanced by the growth of the corporate bond market, this
could see some shrinking in the relative importance of bond markets
in these countries.
As for other segments of the financial sector such as insurance companies,
pension funds and mutual funds, growth is driven largely by three factors.
One is the lack in many of these countries of an extensive system of
social security, necessitating investment in insurance or financial
assets to provide for contingencies and retirement. The second is the
growing privatisation of parts of even the limited insurance and pension
system, encouraging entry of a new set of private institutions, including
foreign ones. And the third is the lack of adequate savings options
for sections of the middle class emerging from the process of rising
per capita incomes. They then turn to investments in mutual funds as
a means to invest small sums in equity or debt markets. However, the
resources mobilised in these sectors too are not percolating into the
productive sectors.
Table
2: Size of LCY Bond Market in % GDP
(Local Sources) |
|
Ratio
of government local currency bonds to GDP (%) |
|
Ratio
of corporate local currency bonds in GDP (%) |
|
|
CN |
HK |
ID |
KR |
MY |
SG |
TH |
CN |
HK |
ID |
KR |
MY |
SG |
TH |
Dec-95 |
|
5.3 |
12.6 |
15 |
6.9 |
|
|
|
12.6 |
0 |
8.9 |
0.5 |
|
|
Dec-00 |
16.6 |
8.2 |
35.4 |
25.7 |
38 |
26.6 |
22.8 |
0.3 |
27.6 |
1.4 |
48.8 |
35.2 |
20.9 |
4.5 |
Dec-05 |
36.4 |
9.2 |
17.1 |
45.9 |
42.6 |
37.4 |
37.6 |
2.8 |
38.8 |
2.1 |
42.1 |
31.7 |
28.8 |
8.1 |
Dec-11 |
33.9 |
37.1 |
11.4 |
47.5 |
56.6 |
47 |
54.5 |
11.4 |
31.9 |
2 |
67 |
38 |
28.2 |
13 |
Finally,
a fourth common feature, but one that is uneven in evolution across countries
is the increase in securitisation and the growth of derivatives markets.
Given the substantial increase in bank credit and its role in financing
a segmented and diverse retail market, banks would want to transfer risk
for a fee. To do that they need to create low risk securities by combining
assets from different markets, geographies and income groups. Once the
securitisation process begins, the distance to complex derivatives is
short, and there is a replication of the market for complex and opaque
assets in Asian developing countries as well.
The implications of these features of the evolution of Asian finance need
emphasising. The functional school of finance and the votaries of financial
liberalisation it has spawned make a case for financial diversification,
financial deepening (with a higher ratio of financial assets to GDP),
and increased financial intermediation on the grounds that it facilitates
the process of intermediation between savers and investors and does so
in the most ''efficient'' way possible. This suggests that finance is
an instrument facilitating investment from the supply side by mobilising
capital and channelling it to the high return projects that might otherwise
be deprived of needed support.
However, as noted above, the recent Asian experience would suggest that
financial proliferation largely facilitates new lines of business in financial
services and affects the real economy more from the demand side through
the debt-financed household expenditure it promotes. One consequence is
that excessive exposure to retail markets becomes a source of fragility
in these countries just as it did in the developed countries.
As compared to this it was during the years of regulation and so-called
''financial repression'' with its development banks, directed credit programmes
and differential interest rates, that efforts were made to channel finance
into productive activities, including in sectors like agriculture that
would have been otherwise deprived of credit at reasonable interest rates.
During those years finance was important as a supply side facilitator
of investment, but the proliferation of financial markets, institutions
and instruments was limited. That did not, however, limit but rather helped
the financing of the real economy.
*
This article was originally published in the Business Line on 3 September
2012. |