All these are arguments that have been advanced time and again, even
if not necessarily from within the mainstream. What is revealing is
that Stiglitz holds that when he chose to use his position to change
what was obviously bad policy, officials and economists at the IMF blamed
the board of directors, influenced by the Treasury, as being the cause
for inertia, while elements in the board argued that the economists
were in control. To quote Stiglitz, "it was maddening, not just
because the IMF's inertia was so hard to stop but because, with everything
going on behind closed doors, it was impossible to know who was the
obstacle to change."
That indictment is more than damaging. It comes in a context where
one of the principal contributions of the spring meetings was consensus
over a view that the IMF has been espousing for some time now. This
is that greater transparency in policy-making is the key to improving
the functioning of national economies as well as the international financial
system. Unfortunately for the Fund, the spring meetings began in the
midst of turmoil in U.S. and world stock markets, which had generated
fears of a real economic slowdown. This turmoil was led by a collapse
of the Nasdaq index from the speculative highs it had reached in recent
months, indicating that even in the most free and transparent U.S. economy,
financial markets do not work.
The lack of transparency in the IMF's functioning does not stop with
the kind of experiences focussed on by Stiglitz. It took its crudest
form in the recent muddle over the appointment of a successor to Michel
Camdessus who chose to step down as managing director of the IMF before
his third term was through. If allowed to make the decision, the U.S.
would have liked to fill the gap with Stanley Fischer, the first deputy
managing director of the IMF. But in the democratic and transparent
world of neo-colonial domination, all games are fair. For fear of war,
all spoils won are equally divided. In the convention that guides that
division, the U.S. gets the right to nominate its own citizen at the
head of the World Bank and the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). Europe gets to keep the formal headship of the IMF.
However Europe, unlike the U.S., is no single country. While united
against the U.S. and celebrating monetary union, deep divisions simmer
under a yet to be fully formed European identity. These tensions, and
the fact that France with Jacques DeLarosiere and then with Michel Camdessus
had occupied the European seat at the IMF for 22 years, convinced Germany
and its Chancellor, Gerard Shroeder, that Germany being Europe's natural
leader it was time the seat was occupied by a German. France, initially
hopeful of retaining the chair, gave in to the German claim. Italy,
with a couple of eligible candidates in hand, also made a bid, but withdrew
in deference to European unity. All this would have made the task easier
if Germany's first choice, chronologically speaking, Caio Koch-Weser,
was not considered by many as being a poor choice. But with unity vis-a-vis
the U.S. being of paramount importance, the Europeans gave in to Shroeder's
zeal for installing Koch-Weser in Washington at any cost.
It was left to the U.S. to test the delicate diplomatic balance and
threaten a veto of the German nominee. It was in the face of that threat
that Shroeder had to offer another candidate in the form of Horst Kohler,
who finally won the race, though he has been widely described as a lame
duck for the job. In the words of The Financial Times: "His relationship
with the irascible Larry Summers, the U.S. Treasury Secretary, starts
off on the cool side of lukewarm, and Mr. Kohler evokes little more
enthusiasm in Paris, Rome and London."
But the Kohler appointment did not happen before Japan had staked a
claim for the top job at the Fund for its own Eisuke Sakakibara, an
internationally acclaimed economist-diplomat renowned for an ability
to influence foreign exchange markets. He was favoured by many. Besides
violating the convention that a European acceptable to the U.S. must
occupy the Chair at the IMF, Sakakibara's candidature must have been
anathema given his strident criticism of the way the IMF handled the
South-East Asian crisis. In the event, power prevailed over reason,
and Sakakibara too withdrew in favour of Kohler. This episode in the
IMF's history does not just starkly reveal who dominates this multilateral
forum, but also brings to the fore the utter lack of transparency in
deciding on the person who should play the role of free market messiah
for the next five years.
Informed journalistic reports make clear that secretive diplomatic
efforts and transatlantic phone calls were the means by which the slot
was finally filled without any further public display of discord. No
sane, thinking person can believe that an organisation which headhunts
its chief in this fashion displays even a modicum of transparency. Which
is what makes the IMF's effort to use the excuse of transparency to
force market economics down the throats of a reticent, crisis-ridden
Third World appalling, to say the least. But there is little reason
to be appalled. All it takes is to understand that the transparency
slogan is just one more confidence trick on the part of a visibly incompetent,
but still domineering, international elite to straddle the globe with
impunity. This hollow grandeur only reinforces the perception that the
IMF is in a state of imperial decay.