Thus,
in the Syangja model, groups of people (in both mixed and single-sex
groups) form themselves into village or community organisations (VOs),
which then undertake a system of thrift and credit provision. Credit
is both from a revolving fund of received savings and from the VO which
itself borrows from higher tiers. While the initial guidelines may be
suggested by the external agency, basically the decisions about required
savings from all members, amount of loan disbursed, timing of repayment,
and so on, are made by the members of the VO themselves, who also appoint
a Chairperson and a Manager.
In
addition, the VO decides about the implementation of infrastructure
grants which have been provided. A majority of these have gone into
drinking water projects which are sorely needed in the countryside,
and which are already estimated to have reduced the incidence of water-borne
diseases in the relevant areas. Other infrastructure projects have included
irrigation schemes and roads.
The
VOs themselves are then organised into CMCs (Chairperson- Manager Conferences)
which meet once a month, choose their own chair and decide about allocations
across the village organisations. A higher tier is composed of the Local
Trust Fund Board, an elected body with some bureaucratic representations
as well.
All
this may sound like simply the creation of more and more village bureaucrats,
but the reality is rather different. First impressions suggest that
most of the members of the VOs have a great sense of belonging to and
being able to control the decisions of the VO, and view these different
tiers of management as both necessary and important to create a link
with other villages in the area.
The
CMCs in turn become more than simply a formal meeting of the constituent
groups. One such meeting held recently in Keware village was heavily
attended despite the difficulty of crossing hilly terrain to get to
the meeting place. It was also lively and wide ranging in terms of discussions.
The participants thought about new schemes, such as the possibility
of providing livestock insurance, and exchanged notes about important
matters and local and national news. Several people pointed out that
this was an important means, especially in a mountainous area where
communication is otherwise difficult, of getting information and working
out common strategies to deal with problems.
There
are two possible caveats to the currently functioning system. Most decisions
are taken through consensus rather than vote, and this can often be
a problem when power is asymmetrically held. Also, there are still problems
of relative exclusion of the poorest households : while they are typically
members of the VO who make the necessary (and relatively small amount)
of required savings, they usually lack the confidence and repayment
capacity to take loans. For this reason, they typically still remain
dependent upon traditional moneylenders who are more flexible in timing
and often adjust the loan in other ways such as labour services, and
to that extent have been denied the possible benefits of this programme.
Otherwise, however, for most of the rest of the membership, the significance
of traditional moneylenders has declined.
The
material benefits of such a programme - in living standards and changes
in patterns of consumption and savings - are fairly easy to see, even
if they are limited in scope. Thus, in the concerned villages there
has been improvement in some important infrastructure areas, whether
in the form of new roads, better access to drinking water, sanitation
facilities, or irrigation for cultivation. But the real benefits of
this programme are probably less material and more social in nature.
Thus,
the now recognised role of such organisations in terms of empowering
women is evident here as well. Not only do more women participate and
get involved in these activities, but the groups then become vehicles
for broader social mobilisation and consciousness raising. Several women
pointed out how they have gained in confidence, feel more able to participate
actively in public life, and may choose to benefit from various kinds
of training. The process of creating, being involved in and running
these organisations also requires various kinds of skill, not just bookkeeping
but other skills, which are made evident and then developed by the programme.
increasingly, the VOs have been showing initiative in asking for or
organising training programmes that provide for skills that are felt
to be in short supply, whether in animal husbandry or in agriculture
or in other manufacturing and service activities.
One
of the most important effects is probably in terms of the effects on
the VO members in terms of increasing their capacity to respond and
participate as citizens. Thus, not only is there greater recognition
of the advantages within a village, of working together and co-operation,
but the relationship with other public and private agents outside the
village also becomes more active and informed. thus, some awareness
of the issues involved in building local infrastructure allows for a
more reasoned assessment of public activities in this regard, and also
builds more community participation in assessing other economic activities
of the state and other big players in the area.
This
is a feature which is a fundamental requirement of true democracy, and
any institutions which act as catalysts to enable people to demand more
control over various aspects of their own quotidian life are therefore
of great importance. This is why the significance of programmes such
as this one in Nepal go well beyond the specific effects of certain
loans, and extend into the conditions for ensuring more enduring democratic
participation in economic decision-making. Surely there is an important
lesson in this for the rest of South Asia.