What is remarkable is that even the commitment to agricultural policy
reform in the form of reduced support and lower trade barriers is
being given up. Between 1991 and 1997, the OECD Secretariat reports,
as part of the run up to and the aftermath of the Uruguay Round, producer
support fell from just above 40 per cent of farm receipts to 30 per
cent. But over 1998 and 1999 when farm prices worldwide have been
on the decline to just above half the 1995 peak in the case of oilseeds
and wheat, the extent of support has risen sharply from 30 to 40 per
cent, that is, to levels before the adjustment to a likely post-Uruguay
world began. OECD governments clearly rate the need to protect their
richest farmers from the adverse consequences of world-price volatility,
way above their 'commitment' to a freer trade regime and a 'distortion-free'
environment.
Even the OECD Secretariat admits that all of this does not bode well
for the emerging and transition economies (ETEs), defined to include
the transition economies in Central and Eastern Europe as well as
large emerging economies such China, India, Brazil and Indonesia.
In its view, "agricultural trade barriers, export subsidies,
and domestic support in OECD countries have limited the potential
benefits of free trade in agriculture for ETEs," where "agriculture
is much more important in income and employment terms." Given
this, even the most committed among those belonging to the free trade
faith need to consider whether protection for their farmers through
means that are either WTO compatible or incompatible, should be sacrificed
at the altar of their beliefs, at a time when policies being pursued
by their trading partners substantially curtail their access to potential
markets.
The problem is that given the adoption of IMF-inspired fiscal regimes,
developing country governments, such as in India, are voluntarily
forsaking policies aimed at providing direct producer support or measures
that indirectly sustain such policies by absorbing surpluses to feed
an extensive public distribution system issuing food at subsidised
prices to the consumer. This puts them in a self-imposed double bind.
To begin with, they are not willing to imitate, rather than listen
to, developed country governments when it comes to blatantly violating
WTO commitments, and find heir markets flooded with surpluses from
abroad. Secondly, they are not sharp-witted enough to drop their obsession
with the size of the fiscal deficit at the expense of all else, even
while the IMF itself praises the Southeast Asian governments currently
engaged in pump-priming themselves out of the recession induced by
the financial crises of 1997. This limits their ability to offer WTO-compatible
support to their agricultural sectors.
In the event, developing-country governments end up opening doors
to their own markets at a time when their access to developed country
markets are being reduced, and denying their much-poorer farmers much-needed
support even while the developed countries back their rich agriculturists.
This can only be because the elite which currently governs in these
contexts has much to gain by submitting to the duplicity of western
governments, and is willing to sacrifice its farming community as
part of the bargain.
One indicator of this attitude
in the Indian context is the incompetent manner in which the present
government is dealing with the mounting stocks of wheat which have
accumulated because issue prices of food supplied through the PDS
have more than doubled over the last two years and the spread and
coverage of the PDS has not expanded enough. The result has been that
instead of the food subsidy declining with the higher issue prices,
they are showing signs of rising sharply because of increasing stockholding
costs. This simple message, which somehow seems to have eluded the
Finance Minister when he refused to roll back PDS price hikes, has
now seemed to have struck home. The recent decision to resort to open
market sales of wheat stocks in Punjab at a price linked to the economic
cost of wheat procured from that state is in effect an effort to roll-back
the prices at which the government will offload its stocks, although
not to PDS consumers but only to traders and millers. Yet, the latter
are reportedly not too willing to lift stocks even at prices substantially
below PDS prices, unless export opportunities are opened up through
export subsidies. The whole system appears to be geared to trying
to run down stocks and incur subsidies but without benefit to domestic
consumers. This is strange because while an expanded PDS would be
perfectly WTO-compatible, export subsidies in any form would not.
It would not be unexpected therefore, if soon after exports were allowed
directly or indirectly from FCI stocks, the US or Europe would call
for restrictions on the FCI's functioning or even demand that it dismantled.
If so, not only would the PDS atrophy but so would the current system
of minimum support prices. The gainers, while including domestic traders
and millers close to the party currently in power, would be international
trading giants like Cargill. The losers inevitably would be consumers
and farmers. The war would have been lost by a series of own goals
based on the fallacy that somehow all that is needed to reduce subsidies
is to make things more expensive for the poor.