|
|
|
|
A
Theoretical Note on Kerala-Style Decentralized Planning |
|
Apr
14th 2004, Prabhat Patnaik
|
|
The
''Peoples' Plan campaign'' in Kerala, which led to
the devolution of nearly a third of the Plan outlay
of the State to Local Self Government Institutions
(LSGIs) to spend on projects of their choice, has
of late generated much controversy. Many have even
argued that ''decentralization'' is a part of the
imperialist agenda and that the Left's adoption of
it represents a capitulation (which can be explained
only through the ''erroneous'' activities and understanding
of some leading Comrades). This entire line of criticism
however misses a basic point, namely that the ''decentralization''
proposed by the Left, propagated through the Peoples'
Plan campaign, and implemented during the years of
LDF rule is fundamentally different from the ''decentralization''
promoted by the World Bank and other imperialist agencies.
While the ''decentralization'' agenda of the Left
is a means of carrying class-struggle forward, of
buttressing the class-strength of the rural poor by
developing institutions where they can, in principle,
assert themselves directly and hence more effectively,
the ''decentralization'' promoted by the imperialist
agencies has precisely the opposite objective, of
blunting class-struggle, of encouraging a scenario
of ''obedient-and-supplicant-villagers-being-patronized-by-NGOs'',
and of substituting the concept of the ''Rights''
of the people by the concept of ''Self-Help''. In
pushing their agenda, it is in the interests of the
imperialist agencies to pretend as if there is no
difference between their programme and the Left programme.
But for that very reason it is essential for the Left
to emphasize in every possible manner the difference
between the two agendas, to highlight the specificity
of the imperialist agenda, if it is to defeat the
latter.
It
is a deliberate ploy of imperialism to borrow concepts
from the Left and incorporate them into its own lexicon
after giving them a different meaning. This habit
of borrowing concepts serves many purposes: first,
the analytical depth that is usually associated with
any Left concept is mistakenly attributed to the imperialist
concept as well and imparts a prestige to imperialist
theory; secondly, since the same concept is used by
the enemies of the Left as by the Left itself, it
creates confusion in Left ranks, and blunts a basic
weapon of the latter, namely theoretical clarity;
thirdly, by creating fuzziness around basic concepts
imperialism seeks to destroy clarity of thinking in
society as a whole, which helps to establish and perpetuate
its hegemony.
Consider an example. Terms like "structure",
"structural change", "structuralism",
and "structural reforms" were originally
developed in the ranks of the Left as a critique of
imperialist theory. As against the standard imperialist
view that the free market was the panacea for the
ills of the third world, the Left advanced the theory
that the third world needed a rupture with the structures
inherited from its colonial and semi-colonial past,
via land reforms, via de-linking from the imperialist-dominated
world market, via building up the public sector as
a bulwark against metropolitan capital, and via a
rapid process of planned industrialization. This was
so clear an intellectual divide that the term "structure"
was as much a short-hand for Left thinking as "market"
was for the Right. And yet today the term "structural
adjustment" has become a central part of Fund-Bank
theory; it is given a meaning that is precisely the
opposite of what it originally meant within the Left
lexicon, namely "opening" the economy to
the free play of the so-called market forces. Imperialist
agencies simply took over a Left concept and used
it for their own purposes after giving it a different
meaning.
The same is happening today to the concept of "decentralization",
which has been, for a very long time, and particularly
in India for the last quarter of a century, i.e. since
1977 when the Left Front government came to power
in West Bengal, an integral part of the Left lexicon.
This was long before the so-called "economic
reforms" began and the Fund and the Bank started
strutting around on the Indian scene. But soon they,
and other imperialist agencies like the ADB and DFID,
started talking about "decentralization"
as if they had invented the term, and giving it a
fundamentally different meaning from what it had as
part of the Left lexicon. So successful has been their
ploy that today, as mentioned earlier, many who claim
to owe allegiance to the Left have actually started
demanding that the Left should have nothing to do
with decentralization which is an imperialist concept
and hence a part of an imperialist conspiracy. This
is "liquidationism" at the level of theory.
Instead of exposing the imperialist game of taking
over Left concepts and exploiting their legitimacy
for its own nefarious ends, this perception actually
accepts imperialist claims of having authored the
concepts themselves, and abandons legitimate democratic
issues on the absurd ground that if imperialism is
talking "about the same thing" then they
cannot be legitimate democratic issues. The whole
point however is that imperialism is not talking about
the same thing.
My purpose in this paper is to distinguish between
imperialism's concept of decentralization and the
Left concept which, as already noted, is far older
and rooted in its own philosophical tradition. I shall
not however, for reasons of space, be going into the
whole gamut of Left thinking on this question. I shall
confine myself only to the concept of decentralized
planning as conceived of and practised by the LDF
government in Kerala, examine its specificities, and
show the difference between this practice and the
one advocated by the imperialist agencies.
Two basic questions can be asked about Kerala's "decentralization"
experiment. First, what is its relationship with planning?
And secondly, what is its link with class-struggle
in the countryside? In this section I shall address
the first of these questions, keeping the second to
the next section. Section IV discusses the contrast
between this "decentralization" and the
imperialist concept. The last section contains some
concluding observations.
Even traditionally, i.e. prior to the intrusion of
the imperialist concept, the term "decentralization"
had been used in different contexts to mean several
different things. To examine the specificity of the
Kerala experiment therefore let me begin by distinguishing
between some of these traditional meanings.
There are at least four different senses in which
the term has been used in the economic literature.
The first is decentralization as in a capitalist market
economy, where there are a number of separate decision-makers,
such as firms and consumers, and the overall functioning
of the economy, its performance in any period and
its dynamics over time, is a resultant of these dispersed
individual decisions. By contrast a planned economy
in its classical meaning is supposed to function on
the basis of centralized decision-making. A comparison
between the two systems of decision-making used to
be a common theme in economics at one time, and the
case for the superiority of the centralized system
was argued on the grounds that it overcame the "anarchy
of the market" to which Marx, and Keynes, in
their different ways had drawn attention[1]
. (Maurice Dobb and Michael Kalecki were perhaps the
most persuasive presenters of this argument).
The other three senses in which the term has been
used refer essentially to the context of a planned
economy itself, but one which despite being planned
is not centralized in the sense of being a "command
economy". The second meaning of the term has
to do with decentralization as an arrangement for
information flow in a planned economy, such as was
proposed famously by Oskar Lange and later by Kornai
and Liptak. Of course the Lange vision of decentralization,
and that of Kornai-Liptak, referred not to actual
decentralization but merely to a procedure of central
planning, to the operation, as Joan Robinson was to
put it, of a "pseudo-market" in a planned
economy, so that the plan gets finalized on the basis
of a two-way flow of information between the central
planner and the individual enterprises.
The idea is the following. The Central Planner announces
a set of prices (these prices are only announced,
they do not actually rule in any market), and on the
basis of these prices the enterprises inform the Planner
how much they would like to produce in order to maximize
the enterprise profits. Since the sum of these output
decisions would differ from what the Planner might
wish to have as the Plan target, it would then announce
a set of revised prices; and so the ''iteration'',
i.e. the to-and-fro movement of information, would
continue until a final Plan is prepared. The sole
advantage of this ''iteration'' proposal is that the
Planner does not need to have detailed knowledge of
all the resources and raw materials available with
each and every enterprise[2].
Even though this ''iteration'' is supposed to occur
only through a "pseudo-market", i.e. only
through an exchange of information to which there
is no actual market counterpart, one could in principle
even make this ''iteration'' occur in actual practice.
The Central Planner could announce a set of prices,
leave it to enterprises to produce amounts they like
at these prices, and hold unsold amounts as stocks.
In all cases where the stocks were large, the prices
could be lowered and where they were small, prices
could be increased, and so on. There would not then
be one overall final plan, but a series of adjustments
on an initial blue-print, approximating towards but
never actually reaching a final consistent document.
Room would have to be made in such a case through
appropriate institutional provisions (e.g. larger
inventories etc.) for the realization of such an approximate
plan, but a planned economy of this sort could still
function in a manner that curbs on the whole the anarchy
of capitalism.
The third sense in which the term decentralization
has been used is in the context of the view that the
unit over which planning is done is not the country's
economy as a whole but the economies of particular
parts of it. Here we have not a change in the model
of central planning, but a splitting up of the units
over which the central plans are formulated. (And
if we are talking not of a fully-planned economy but
of a mixed or partially-planned economy, such as India
was in its dirigiste phase, then "decentralization"
would refer to a reduction in the size of the unit
over which such partial planning is done.) An idea
was current among several progressive thinkers in
the country at one time that, barring a few areas
such as defence, communications, and foreign policy
etc., the rest of the functions of the government,
including in particular development, should be undertaken
by the State governments. Whether the Centre makes
actual resources available to the States for this
purpose, or resource-raising powers are themselves
transferred to the States, this perception of "decentralization"
amounts to a change not in the relation between the
plan and enterprises but in the unit over which planning,
of whatever variety, occurs.
The fourth concept of "decentralization"
refers to a situation where, if an individual or collective
unit is to be the beneficiary of a set of projects
in a particular sphere, then they should be allowed
to finalize the precise mix of such projects. This
is nothing else but an extension of the principle
that when it comes to certain kinds of goods, it is
better that individuals (or families) are given the
cash to purchase these goods[3]
, rather than these goods being made directly available
to them, a principle that often goes under the grandiose
(and, in capitalist conditions, misleading) title
of "consumers' sovereignty". In certain
spheres in other words, "users' sovereignty"
should be respected.
The last two meanings of the term "decentralization"
might appear to be too close for drawing any worthwhile
distinction between them, but there is a significant
difference in "quantity" between the two
cases which almost amounts to a difference in "quality".
I perceive these four cases in the following terms
respectively: "decentralization as anarchy",
"decentralization as iteration", "decentralization
as multiplication" and "decentralization
as users' sovereignty". Of course in practice
these different cases come not in pure form but often
jumbled up, and neat pigeon-holing of any actual case
of "decentralization" into any one of these
cases may be difficult; nonetheless this distinction
is useful for assessing the implications of particular
cases of decentralization. For instance it would be
grossly erroneous to see the Kerala case of "decentralization"
through "peoples' planning" as engendering
either "anarchy" or "multiplication"
or mere "iteration". It is quite clearly
of the fourth kind. It does not in principle negate
planning (even of the sort we have in India); rather
it is based on invoking, implicitly, the concept of
"users' sovereignty" as justification for
the devolution of plan funds to LSGIs for undertaking
certain kinds of projects within an overall plan.
Two caveats have to be entered here. First, if a plan
is to have consistency, i.e. various commodity balances
have to be satisfied, then the fact that the mix of
projects is left to the individual LSGIs would have
problematical implications. Flow excess demands and
flow excess supplies of particular commodities would
arise on account of the fact that the decisions of
the individual LSGIs are not co-ordinated ex ante.
But this problem (as in the second case discussed
above of real-life ''iterative'' planning) can be
resolved through the holding of appropriate inventories.
Secondly, if the LSGIs are to be not merely plan-fund-using
institutions but are to take some initiative in mobilizing
resources of their own and using these for their own
purposes, or even taking on productive roles and using
the proceeds obtained from doing so for their own
purposes, then these activities and the expenditures
generated on account of them would constitute "add-ons"
to the basic plan of the economy. These "add-ons",
since they are not based on any ex ante co-ordination,
could upset the basic balance of the plan by creating
ex ante flow excess demands and supplies. Once again
however the problem can be handled by making prior
provision for such contingencies through the appropriate
provision of inventories or by maintaining a higher
level of planned excess capacity in the productive
sectors within the framework of the plan itself.
It follows then that the "peoples' planning"
experiment of Kerala, while it entails "decentralization",
in the sense that the budgeted amount earmarked as
expenditure on certain items in the plan, such as
rural infrastructure, is handed over to the LSGIs
in order to reflect better the preferences of the
users, does not mean a negation of planning. On the
contrary, it can be defended on the grounds of "users'
sovereignty". True, the amount handed over to
the LSGIs has been fixed as a percentage of the total
plan outlay rather than being independently determined
on the basis of the estimated expenditure under the
relevant heads, but the figure for this percentage
itself has been arrived at by considering the approximate
proportion of expenditure actually incurred in the
past on these items. Hence, the "users' sovereignty"
argument is not undermined by the fact of the devolution
being fixed as a percentage of plan funds.
The additional merit of the Kerala experiment consists
of the fact that "users' sovereignty" is
sought to be exercised through collective bodies directly
or through their democratically elected representatives.
This brings me however to the second question that
can be asked about Kerala's decentralization experiment.
[1]
Keynes who was a liberal bourgeois economist aware
of the fact that capitalism was subject to anarchy,
wanted to preserve capitalism against the socialist
threat by reforming it so that the basic property
relations remained unchanged but there was "socialization
of investment" through State intervention.
[2] For a discussion of these issues
see Maurice Dobb (1969).
[3]
For
a discussion of this principle as well as where it
should not apply see Dobb (1969), Chapter 10.
|
|
| 1 |
2 |
Next
Page >> |
|
Print
this Page |
|
|
|
|